This original engrossing of uncultivated lands, though a great, might have
been but a transitory evil. They might soon have been divided again, and
broke into small parcels either by succession or by alienation. The law of
primogeniture hindered them from being divided by succession: the introduction
of entails prevented their being broke into small parcels by alienation.
When land, like movables, is considered as the means only of subsistence
and enjoyment, the natural law of succession divides it, like them, among
all the children of the family; of an of whom the subsistence and enjoyment
may be supposed equally dear to the father. This natural law of succession
accordingly took place among the Romans, who made no more distinction between
elder and younger, between male and female, in the inheritance of lands than
we do in the distribution of movables. But when land was considered as the
means, not of subsistence merely, but of power and protection, it was thought
better that it should descend undivided to one. In those disorderly times
every great landlord was a sort of petty prince. His tenants were his subjects.
He was their judge, and in some respects their legislator in peace, and their
leader in war. He made war according to his own discretion, frequently against
his neighbours, and sometimes against his sovereign. The security of a landed
estate, therefore, the protection which its owner could afford to those who
dwelt on it, depended upon its greatness. To divide it was to ruin it, and
to expose every part of it to be oppressed and swallowed up by the incursions
of its neighbours. The law of primogeniture, therefore, came to take place,
not immediately, indeed, but in process of time, in the succession of landed
estates, for the same reason that it has generally taken place in that of
monarchies, though not always at their first institution. That the power,
and consequently the security of the monarchy, may not be weakened by division,
it must descend entire to one of the children. To which of them so important
a preference shall be given must be determined by some general rule, founded
not upon the doubtful distinctions of personal merit, but upon some plain
and evident difference which can admit of no dispute. Among the children
of the same family, there can be no indisputable difference but that of sex,
and that of age. The male sex is universally preferred to the female; and
when all other things are equal, the elder everywhere takes place of the
younger. Hence the origin of the right of primogeniture, and of what is called
lineal succession.
Laws frequently continue in force long after the circumstances which first
gave occasion to them, and which could alone render them reasonable, are
no more. In the present state of Europe, the proprietor of a single acre
of land is as perfectly secure of his possession as the proprietor of a hundred
thousand. The right of primogeniture, however, still continues to be respected,
and as of all institutions it is the fittest to support the pride of family
distinctions, it is still likely to endure for many centuries. In every other
respect, nothing can be more contrary to the real interest of a numerous
family than a right which, in order to enrich one, beggars all the rest of
the children.
Entails are the natural consequences of the law of primogeniture. They were
introduced to preserve a certain lineal succession, of which the law of primogeniture
first gave the idea, and to hinder any part of the original estate from being
carried out of the proposed line either by gift, or devise, or alienation;
either by the folly, or by the misfortune of any of its successive owners.
They were altogether unknown to the Romans. Neither their substitutions nor
fideicommisses bear any resemblance to entails, though some French lawyers
have thought proper to dress the modern institution in the language and garb
of those ancient ones.
When great landed estates were a sort of principalities, entails might not
be unreasonable. Like what are called the fundamental laws of some monarchies,
they might frequently hinder the security of thousands from being endangered
by the caprice or extravagance of one man. But in the present state of Europe,
when small as well as great estates derive their security from the laws of
their country, nothing can be more completely absurd. They are founded upon
the most absurd of all suppositions, the supposition that every successive
generation of men have not an equal right to the earth, and to all that it
possesses; but that the property of the present generation should be restrained
and regulated according to the fancy of those who died perhaps five hundred
years ago. Entails, however, are still respected through the greater part
of Europe, in those countries particularly in which noble birth is a necessary
qualification for the enjoyment either of civil or military honours. Entails
are thought necessary for maintaining this exclusive privilege of the nobility
to the great offices and honours of their country; and that order having
usurped one unjust advantage over the rest of their fellow citizens, lest
their poverty should render it ridiculous, it is thought reasonable that
they should have another. The common law of England, indeed, is said to abhor
perpetuities, and they are accordingly more restricted there than in any
other European monarchy; though even England is not altogether without them.
In Scotland more than one-fifth, perhaps more than one-third, part of the
whole lands of the country are at present supposed to be under strict entail.
Great tracts of uncultivated land were, in this manner, not only engrossed
by particular families, but the possibility of their being divided again
was as much as possible precluded for ever. It seldom happens, however, that
a great proprietor is a great improver. In the disorderly times which gave
birth to those barbarous institutions, the great proprietor was sufficiently
employed in defending his own territories, or in extending his jurisdiction
and authority over those of his neighbours. He had no leisure to attend to
the cultivation and improvement of land. When the establishment of law and
order afforded him this leisure, he often wanted the inclination, and almost
always the requisite abilities. If the expense of his house and person either
equalled or exceeded his revenue, as it did very frequently, he had no stock
to employ in this manner. If he was an economist, he generally found it more
profitable to employ his annual savings in new purchases than in the improvement
of his old estate. To improve land with profit, like all other commercial
projects, requires an exact attention to small savings and small gains, of
which a man born to a great fortune, even though naturally frugal, is very
seldom capable. The situation of such a person naturally disposes him to
attend rather to ornament which pleases his fancy than to profit for which
he has so little occasion. The elegance of his dress, of his equipage, of
his house, and household furniture, are objects which from his infancy he
has been accustomed to have some anxiety about. The turn of mind which this
habit naturally forms follows him when he comes to think of the improvement
of land. He embellishes perhaps four or five hundred acres in the neighbourhood
of his house, at ten times the expense which the land is worth after all
his improvements; and finds that if he was to improve his whole estate in
the same manner, and he has little taste for any other, he would be a bankrupt
before he had finished the tenth part of it. There still remain in both parts
of the United Kingdom some great estates which have continued without interruption
in the hands of the same family since the times of feudal anarchy. Compare
the present condition of those estates with the possessions of the small
proprietors in their neighbourhood, and you will require no other argument
to convince you how unfavourable such extensive property is to improvement.
If little improvement was to be expected from such great proprietors, still
less was to be hoped for from those who occupied the land under them. In
the ancient state of Europe, the occupiers of land were all tenants at will.
They were all or almost all slaves; but their slavery was of a milder kind
than that known among the ancient Greeks and Romans, or even in our West
Indian colonies. They were supposed to belong more directly to the land than
to their master. They could, therefore, be sold with it, but not separately.
They could marry, provided it was with the consent of their master; and he
could not afterwards dissolve the marriage by selling the man and wife to
different persons. If he maimed or murdered any of them, he was liable to
some penalty, though generally but to a small one. They were not, however,
capable of acquiring property. Whatever they acquired was acquired to their
master, and he could take it from them at pleasure. Whatever cultivation
and improvement could be carried on by means of such slaves was properly
carried on by their master. It was at his expense. The seed, the cattle,
and the instruments of husbandry were all his. It was for his benefit. Such
slaves could acquire nothing but their daily maintenance. It was properly
the proprietor himself, therefore, that, in this case, occupied his own lands,
and cultivated them by his own bondmen. This species of slavery still subsists
in Russia, Poland, Hungary, Bohemia, Moravia, and other parts of Germany.
It is only in the western and southwestern provinces of Europe that it has
gradually been abolished altogether.
But if great improvements are seldom to be expected from great proprietors,
they are least of all to be expected when they employ slaves for their workmen.
The experience of all ages and nations, I believe, demonstrates that the
work done by slaves, though it appears to cost only their maintenance, is
in the end the dearest of any. A person who can acquire no property, can
have no other interest but to eat as much, and to labour as little as possible.
Whatever work he does beyond what is sufficient to purchase his own maintenance
can be squeezed out of him by violence only, and not by any interest of his
own. In ancient Italy, how much the cultivation of corn degenerated, how
unprofitable it became to the master when it fell under the management of
slaves, is remarked by both Pliny and Columella. In the time of Aristotle
it had not been much better in ancient Greece. Speaking of the ideal republic
described in the laws of Plato, to maintain five thousand idle men (the number
of warriors supposed necessary for its defence) together with their women
and servants, would require, he says, a territory of boundless extent and
fertility, like the plains of Babylon.
The pride of man makes him love to domineer, and nothing mortifies him so
much as to be obliged to condescend to persuade his inferiors. Wherever the
law allows it, and the nature of the work can afford it, therefore, he will
generally prefer the service of slaves to that of freemen. The planting of
sugar and tobacco can afford the expense of slave-cultivation. The raising
of corn, it seems, in the present times, cannot. In the English colonies,
of which the principal produce is corn, the far greater part of the work
is done by freemen. The late resolution of the Quakers in Pennsylvania to
set at liberty all their negro slaves may satisfy us that their number cannot
be very great. Had they made any considerable part of their property, such
a resolution could never have been agreed to. In our sugar colonies, on the
contrary, the whole work is done by slaves, and in our tobacco colonies a
very great part of it. The profits of a sugar-plantation in any of our West
Indian colonies are generally much greater than those of any other cultivation
that is known either in Europe or America; and the profits of a tobacco plantation,
though inferior to those of sugar, are superior to those of corn, as has
already been observed. Both can afford the expense of slave-cultivation,
but sugar can afford it still better than tobacco. The number of negroes
accordingly is much greater, in proportion to that of whites, in our sugar
than in our tobacco colonies.
To the slave cultivators of ancient times gradually succeeded a species
of farmers known at present in France by the name of metayers. They are called
in Latin, Coloni partiarii. They have been so long in disuse in England that
at present I know no English name for them. The proprietor furnished them
with the seed, cattle, and instruments of husbandry, the whole stock, in
short, necessary for cultivating the farm. The produce was divided equally
between the proprietor and the farmer, after setting aside what was judged
necessary for keeping up the stock, which was restored to the proprietor
when the farmer either quitted, or was turned out of the farm.
Land occupied by such tenants is properly cultivated at the expense of the
proprietor as much as that occupied by slaves. There is, however, one very
essential difference between them. Such tenants, being freemen, are capable
of acquiring property, and having a certain proportion of the produce of
the land, they have a plain interest that the whole produce should be as
great as possible, in order that their own proportion may be so. A slave,
on the contrary, who can acquire nothing but his maintenance, consults his
own ease by making the land produce as little as possible over and above
that maintenance. It is probable that it was partly upon account of this
advantage, and partly upon account of the encroachments which the sovereign,
always jealous of the great lords, gradually encouraged their villains to
make upon their authority, and which seem at last to have been such as rendered
this species of servitude altogether inconvenient, that tenure in villanage
gradually wore out through the greater part of Europe. The time and manner,
however, in which so important a revolution was brought about is one of the
most obscure points in modern history. The Church of Rome claims great merit
in it; and it is certain that so early as the twelfth century, Alexander
III published a bull for the general emancipation of slaves. It seems, however,
to have been rather a pious exhortation than a law to which exact obedience
was required from the faithful. Slavery continued to take place almost universally
for several centuries afterwards, till it was gradually abolished by the
joint operation of the two interests above mentioned, that of the proprietor
on the one hand, and that of the sovereign on the other. A villain enfranchised,
and at the same time allowed to continue in possession of the land, having
no stock of his own, could cultivate it only by means of what the landlord
advanced to him, and must, therefore, have been what the French called a
metayer.
It could never, however, be the interest even of this last species of cultivators
to lay out, in the further improvement of the land, any part of the little
stock which they might save from their own share of the produce, because
the lord, who laid out nothing, was to get one half of whatever it produced.
The tithe, which is but a tenth of the produce, is found to be a very great
hindrance to improvement. A tax, therefore, which amounted to one half must
have been an effectual bar to it. It might be the interest of a metayer to
make the land produce as much as could be brought out of it by means of the
stock furnished by the proprietor; but it could never be his interest to
mix any part of his own with it. In France, where five parts out of six of
the whole kingdom are said to be still occupied by this species of cultivators,
the proprietors complain that their metayers take every opportunity of employing
the master's cattle rather in carriage than in cultivation; because in the
one case they get the whole profits to themselves, in the other they share
them with their landlord. This species of tenants still subsists in some
parts of Scotland. They are called steel-bow tenants. Those ancient English
tenants, who are said by Chief Baron Gilbert and Doctor Blackstone to have
been rather bailiffs of the landlord than farmers properly so called, were
probably of the same kind.
To this species of tenancy succeeded, though by very slow degrees, farmers
properly so called, who cultivated the land with their own stock, paying
a rent certain to the landlord. When such farmers have a lease for a term
of years, they may sometimes find it for their interest to lay out part of
their capital in the further improvement of the farm; because they may sometimes
expect to recover it, with a large profit, before the expiration of the lease.
The possession even of such farmers, however, was long extremely precarious,
and still is so in many parts of Europe. They could before the expiration
of their term be legally outed of their lease by a new purchaser; in England,
even by the fictitious action of a common recovery. If they were turned out
illegally by the violence of their master, the action by which they obtained
redress was extremely imperfect. It did not always reinstate them in the
possession of the land, but gave them damages which never amounted to the
real loss. Even in England, the country perhaps of Europe where the yeomanry
has always been most respected, it was not till about the 14th of Henry VII
that the action of ejectment was invented, by which the tenant recovers,
not damages only but possession, and in which his claim is not necessarily
concluded by the uncertain decision of a single assize. This action has been
found so effectual a remedy that, in the modern practice, when the landlord
has occasion to sue for the possession of the land, he seldom makes use of
the actions which properly belong to him as landlord, the Writ of Right or
the Writ of Entry, but sues in the name of his tenant by the Writ of Ejectment.
In England, therefore, the security of the tenant is equal to that of the
proprietor. In England, besides, a lease for life of forty shillings a year
value is a freehold, and entitles the lessee to vote for a Member of Parliament;
and as a great part of the yeomanry have freeholds of this kind, the whole
order becomes respectable to their landlords on account of the political
consideration which this gives them. There is, I believe, nowhere in Europe,
except in England, any instance of the tenant building upon the land of which
he had no lease, and trusting that the honour of his landlord would take
no advantage of so important an improvement. Those laws and customs so favourable
to the yeomanry have perhaps contributed more to the present grandeur of
England than all their boasted regulations of commerce taken together.
The law which secures the longest leases against successors of every kind
is, so far as I know, peculiar to Great Britain. It was introduced into Scotland
so early as 1449, a law of James II. Its beneficial influence, however, has
been much obstructed by entails; the heirs of entail being generally restrained
from letting leases for any long term of years, frequently for more than
one year. A late Act of Parliament has, in this respect, somewhat slackened
their fetters, though they are still by much too strait. In Scotland, besides,
as no leasehold gives a vote for a Member of Parliament, the yeomanry are
upon this account less respectable to their landlords than in England.
In other parts of Europe, after it was found convenient to secure tenants
both against heirs and purchasers, the term of their security was still limited
to a very short period; in France, for example, to nine years from the commencement
of the lease. It has in that country, indeed, been lately extended to twenty-seven,
a period still too short to encourage the tenant to make the most important
improvements. The proprietors of land were anciently the legislators of every
part of Europe. The laws relating to land, therefore, were all calculated
for what they supposed the interest of the proprietor. It was for his interest,
they had imagined, that no lease granted by any of his predecessors should
hinder him from enjoying, during a long term of years, the full value of
his land. Avarice and injustice are always short-sighted, and they did not
foresee how much this regulation must obstruct improvement, and thereby hurt
in the long-run the real interest of the landlord.
The farmers too, besides paying the rent, were anciently, it was supposed,
bound to perform a great number of services to the landlord, which were seldom
either specified in the lease, or regulated by any precise rule, but by the
use and wont of the manor or barony. These services, therefore, being almost
entirely arbitrary, subjected the tenant to many vexations. In Scotland the
abolition of all services not precisely stipulated in the lease has in the
course of a few years very much altered for the better the condition of the
yeomanry of that country.
The public services to which the yeomanry were bound were not less arbitrary
than the private ones. To make and maintain the high roads, a servitude which
still subsists, I believe, everywhere, though with different degrees of oppression
in different countries, was not the only one. When the king's troops, when
his household or his officers of any kind passed through any part of the
country, the yeomanry were bound to provide them with horses, carriages,
and provisions, at a price regulated by the purveyor. Great Britain is, I
believe, the only monarchy in Europe where the oppression of purveyance has
been entirely abolished. It still subsists in France and Germany.
The public taxes to which they were subject were as irregular and oppressive
as the services. The ancient lords, though extremely unwilling to grant themselves
any pecuniary aid to their sovereign, easily allowed him to tallage, as they
called it their tenants, and had not knowledge enough to foresee how much
this must in the end affect their own revenue. The taille, as it still subsists
in France, may serve as an example of those ancient tallages. It is a tax
upon the supposed profits of the farmer, which they estimate by the stock
that he has upon the farm. It is his interest, therefore, to appear to have
as little as possible, and consequently to employ as little as possible in
its cultivation, and none in its improvement. Should any stock happen to
accumulate in the hands of a French farmer, the taille is almost equal to
a prohibition of its ever being employed upon the land. This tax, besides,
is supposed to dishonour whoever is subject to it, and to degrade him below,
not only the rank of a gentleman, but that of a burgher, and whoever rents
the lands of another becomes subject to it. No gentleman, nor even any burgher
who has stock, will submit to this degradation. This tax, therefore, not
only hinders the stock which accumulates upon the land from being employed
in its improvement, but drives away an other stock from it. The ancient tenths
and fifteenths, so usual in England in former times, seem, so far as they
affected the land, to have been taxes of the same nature with the taille.
Under all these discouragements, little improvement could be expected from
the occupiers of land. That order of people, with all the liberty and security
which law can give, must always improve under great disadvantages. The farmer,
compared with the proprietor, is as a merchant who trades with borrowed money
compared with one who trades with his own. The stock of both may improve,
but that of the one, with only equal good conduct, must always improve more
slowly than that of the other, on account of the large share of the profits
which is consumed by the interest of the loan. The lands cultivated by the
farmer must, in the same manner, with only equal good conduct, be improved
more slowly than those cultivated by the proprietor, on account of the large
share of the produce which is consumed in the rent, and which, had the farmer
been proprietor, he might have employed in the further improvement of the
land. The station of a farmer besides is, from the nature of things, inferior
to that of a proprietor. Through the greater part of Europe the yeomanry
are regarded as an inferior rank of people, even to the better sort of tradesmen
and mechanics, and in all parts of Europe to the great merchants and master
manufacturers. It can seldom happen, therefore, that a man of any considerable
stock should quit the superior in order to place himself in an inferior station.
Even in the present state of Europe, therefore, little stock is likely to
go from any other profession to the improvement of land in the way of farming.
More does perhaps in Great Britain than in any other country, though even
there the great stocks which are, in some places, employed in farming have
generally been acquired by farming, the trade, perhaps, in which of all others
stock is commonly acquired most slowly. After small proprietors, however,
rich and great farmers are, in every country, the principal improvers. There
are more such perhaps in England than in any other European monarchy. In
the republican governments of Holland and of Berne in Switzerland, the farmers
are said to be not inferior to those of England.