Book
Four:
OF
SYSTEMS OF POLITICAL ECONOMY.
CHAPTER
III
Of
the extraordinary Restraints upon the Importation
of Goods of almost all kinds from those Countries
with which the Balance is supposed to be disadvantageous
Part 1: Of the Unreasonableness of those Restraints
even upon the Principles of the Commercial System
To lay extraordinary restraints upon the those particular countries with which
the importation of goods of almost all kinds from balance of trade is supposed
to be disadvantageous, is the second expedient by which the commercial system
proposes to increase the quantity of gold and silver. Thus in Great Britain,
Silesia lawns may be imported for home consumption upon paying certain duties.
But French cambrics and lawns are prohibited to be imported, except into the
port of London, there to be warehoused for exportation. Higher duties are imposed
upon the wines of France than upon those of Portugal, or indeed of any other
country. By what is called the impost 1692, a duty of five-and-twenty per cent
of the rate or value was laid upon all French goods; while the goods of other
nations were, the greater part of them, subjected to much lighter duties, seldom
exceeding five per cent. The wine, brandy, salt and vinegar of France were
indeed excepted; these commodities being subjected to other heavy duties, either
by other laws, or by particular clauses of the same law. In 1696, a second
duty of twenty-five per cent, the first not having been thought a sufficient
discouragement, was imposed upon all French goods, except brandy; together
with a new duty of five-and-twenty pounds upon the ton of French wine, and
another of fifteen pounds upon the ton of French vinegar. French goods have
never been omitted in any of those general subsidies, or duties of five per
cent, which have been imposed upon all, or the greater part of the goods enumerated
in the book of rates. If we count the one-third and two-third subsidies as
making a complete subsidy between them, there have been five of these general
subsidies; so that before the commencement of the present war seventy-five
per cent may be considered as the lowest duty to which the greater part of
the goods of the growth, produce, or manufacture of France were liable. But
upon the greater part of goods, those duties are equivalent to a prohibition.
The French in their turn have, I believe, treated our goods and manufactures
just as hardly; though I am not so well acquainted with the particular hardships
which they have imposed upon them. Those mutual restraints have put an end
to almost all fair commerce between the two nations, and smugglers are now
the principal importers, either of British goods into France, or of French
goods into Great Britain. The principles which I have been examining in the
foregoing chapter took their origin from private interest and the spirit of
monopoly; those which I am going to examine in this, from national prejudice
and animosity. They are, accordingly, as might well be expected, still more
unreasonable. They are so,
even upon the principles of the commercial system.
First, though it were certain that in the case of a free trade between France
and England, for example, the balance would be in favour of France, it would
by no means follow that such a trade would be disadvantageous to England,
or that the general balance of its whole trade would thereby be turned more
against it. If the wines of France are better and cheaper than those of Portugal,
or its linens than those of Germany, it would be more advantageous for Great
Britain to purchase both the wine and the foreign linen which it had occasion
for of France than of Portugal and Germany. Though the value of the annual
importations from France would thereby be greatly augmented, the value of
the whole annual importations would be diminished, in proportion as the French
goods of the same quality were cheaper than those of the other two countries.
This would be the case, even upon the supposition that the whole French goods
imported were to be consumed in Great Britain.
But, secondly, a great part of them might be re-exported to other countries,
where, being sold with profit, they might bring back a return equal in value,
perhaps, to the prime cost of the whole French goods imported. What has frequently
been said of the East India trade might possibly be true of the French; that
though the greater part of East India goods were bought with gold and silver,
the re-exportation of a part of them to other countries brought back more
gold and silver to that which carried on the trade than the prime cost of
the whole amounted to. One of the most important branches of the Dutch trade,
at present, consists in the carriage of French goods to other European countries.
Some part even of the French wine drank in Great Britain is clandestinely
imported from Holland and Zeeland. If there was either a free trade between
France and England, or if French goods could be imported upon paying only
the same duties as those of other European nations, to be drawn back upon
exportation, England might have some share of a trade which is found so advantageous
to Holland.
Thirdly, and lastly, there is no certain criterion by which we can determine
on which side what is called the balance between any two countries lies,
or which of them exports to the greatest value. National prejudice and animosity,
prompted always by the private interest of particular traders, are the principles
which generally direct our judgment upon all questions concerning it. There
are two criterions, however, which have frequently been appealed to upon
such occasions, the customhouse books and the course of exchange. The custom-house
books, I think, it is now generally acknowledged, are a very uncertain criterion,
on account of the inaccuracy of the valuation at which the greater part of
goods are rated in them. The course of exchange is, perhaps, almost equally
so.
When the exchange between two places, such as London and Paris, is at par,
it is said to be a sign that the debts due from London to Paris are compensated
by those due from Paris to London. On the contrary, when a premium is paid
at London for a bill upon Paris, it is said to be a sign that the debts due
from London to Paris are not compensated by those due from Paris to London,
but that a balance in money must be sent out from the latter place; for the
risk, trouble, and expense of exporting which, the premium is both demanded
and given. But the ordinary state of debt and credit between those two cities
must necessarily be regulated, it is said, by the ordinary course of their
dealings with one another. When neither of them imports from the other to
a greater amount than it exports to that other, the debts and credits of
each may compensate one another. But when one of them imports from the other
to a greater value than it exports to that other, the former necessarily
becomes indebted to the latter in a greater sum than the latter becomes indebted
to it; the debts and credits of each do not compensate one another, and money
must be sent out from that place of which the debts overbalance the credits.
The ordinary course of exchange, therefore, being an indication of the ordinary
state of debt and credit between two places, must likewise be an indication
of the ordinary course of their exports and imports, as these necessarily
regulate that state.
But though the ordinary course of exchange should be allowed to be a sufficient
indication of the ordinary state of debt and credit between any two places,
it would not from thence follow that the balance of trade was in favour of
that place which had the ordinary state of debt and credit in its favour.
The ordinary state of debt and credit between any two places is not always
entirely regulated by the ordinary course of their dealings with one another;
but is often influenced by that of the dealings of either with many other
places. If it is usual, for example, for the merchants of England to pay
for the goods which they buy of Hamburg, Danzig, Riga, etc., by bills upon
Holland, the ordinary state of debt and credit between England and Holland
will not be regulated entirely by the ordinary course of the dealings of
those two countries with one another, but will be influenced by that of the
dealings of England with those other places. England may be obliged to send
out every year money to Holland, though its annual exports to that country
may exceed very much the annual value of its imports from thence; and though
what is called the balance of trade may be very much in favour of England.
In the way, besides, in which the par of exchange has hitherto been computed,
the ordinary course of exchange can afford no sufficient indication that
the ordinary state of debt and credit is in favour of that country which
seems to have, or which is supposed to have, the ordinary course of exchange
in its favour: or, in other words, the real exchange may be, and, in fact,
often is so very different from the computed one, that from the course of
the latter no certain conclusion can, upon many occasions, be drawn concerning
that of the former.
When for a sum of money paid in England, containing, according to the standard
of the English mint, a certain number of ounces of pure silver, you receive
a bill for a sum of money to be paid in France, containing, according to
the standard of the French mint, an equal number of ounces of pure silver,
exchange is said to be at par between England and France. When you pay more,
you are supposed to give a premium, and exchange is said to be against England
and in favour of France. When you pay less, you are supposed to get a premium,
and exchange is said to be against France and in favour of England.
But, first, we cannot always judge of the value of the current money of
different countries by the standard of their respective mints. In some it
is more, in others it is less worn, clipt, and otherwise degenerated from
that standard. But the value of the current coin of every country, compared
with that of any other country, is in proportion not to the quantity of pure
silver which it ought to contain, but to that which it actually does contain.
Before the reformation of the silver coin in King William's time, exchange
between England and Holland, computed in the usual manner according to the
standard of their respective mints, was five-and-twenty per cent against
England. But the value of the current coin of England, as we learn from Mr.
Lowndes, was at that time rather more than five-and-twenty per cent below
its standard value. The real exchange, therefore, may even at that time have
been in favour of England, notwithstanding the computed exchange was so much
against it; a smaller number of ounces of pure silver actually paid in England
may have purchased a bill for a greater number of ounces of pure silver to
be paid in Holland, and the man who was supposed to give may in reality have
got the premium. The French coin was, before the late reformation of the
English gold coin, much less worn than the English, and was perhaps two or
three per cent nearer its standard. If the computed exchange with France,
therefore, was not more than two or three per cent against England, the real
exchange might have been in its favour. Since the reformation of the gold
coin, the exchange has been constantly in favour of England, and against
France.
Secondly, in some countries, the expense of coinage is defrayed by the government;
in others, it is defrayed by the private people who carry their bullion to
the mint, and the government even derives some revenue from the coinage.
In England, it is defrayed by the government, and if you carry a pound weight
of standard silver to the mint, you get back sixty-two shillings, containing
a pound weight of the like standard silver. In France, a duty of eight per
cent is deducted for the coinage, which not only defrays the expense of it,
but affords a small revenue to the government. In England, as the coinage
costs nothing; the current coin can never be much more valuable than the
quantity of bullion which it actually contains. In France, the workmanship,
as you pay for it, adds to the value in the same manner as to that of wrought
plate. A sum of French money, therefore, containing a certain weight of pure
silver, is more valuable than a sum of English money containing an equal
weight of pure silver, and must require more bullion, or other commodities,
to purchase it. Though the current coin of the two countries, therefore,
were equally near the standards of their respective mints, a sum of English
money could not well purchase a sum of French money containing an equal number
of ounces of pure silver, nor consequently a bill upon France for such a
sum. If for such a bill no more additional money was paid than what was sufficient
to compensate the expense of the French coinage, the real exchange might
be at par between the two countries, their debts and credits might mutually
compensate one another, while the computed exchange was considerably in favour
of France. If less than this was paid, the real exchange might be in favour
of England, while the computed was in favour of France.
Thirdly, and lastly, in some places, as at Amsterdam, Hamburg, Venice, etc.,
foreign bills of exchange are paid in what they call bank money; while in
others, as at London, Lisbon, Antwerp, Leghorn, etc., they are paid in the
common currency of the country. What is called bank money is always of more
value than the same nominal sum of common currency. A thousand guilders in
the Bank of Amsterdam, for example, are of more value than a thousand guilders
of Amsterdam currency. The difference between them is called the agio of
the bank, which, at Amsterdam, is generally about five per cent. Supposing
the current money of the two countries equally near to the standard of their
respective mints, and that the one pays foreign bills in this common currency,
while the other pays them in bank money, it is evident that the computed
exchange may be in favour of that which pays in bank money, though the real
exchange should be in favour of that which pays in current money; for the
same reason that the computed exchange may be in favour of that which pays
in better money, or in money nearer to its own standard, though the real
exchange should be in favour of that which pays in worse. The computed exchange,
before the late reformation of the gold coin, was generally against London
with Amsterdam, Hamburg, Venice, and, I believe, with all other places which
pay in what is called bank money. It will by no means follow, however, that
the real exchange was against it. Since the reformation of the gold coin,
it has been in favour of London even with those places. The computed exchange
has generally been in favour of London with Lisbon, Antwerp, Leghorn, and,
if you except France, I believe, with most other parts of Europe that pay
in common currency; and it is not improbable that the real exchange was so
too.
DIGRESSION CONCERNING BANKS OF DEPOSIT,
PARTICULARLY CONCERNING THAT OF AMSTERDAM
The currency of a great state, such as France or England, generally consists
almost entirely of its own coin. Should this currency, therefore, be at any
time worn, clipt, or otherwise degraded below its standard value, the state
by a reformation of its coin can effectually re-establish its currency. But
the currency of a small state, such as Genoa or Hamburg, can seldom consist
altogether in its own coin, but must be made up, in a great measure, of the
coins of all the neighbouring states with which its inhabitants have a continual
intercourse. Such a state, therefore, by reforming its coin, will not always
be able to reform its currency. If foreign bills of exchange are paid in this
currency, the uncertain value of any sum, of what is in its own nature so uncertain,
must render the exchange always very much against such a state, its currency
being, in all foreign states, necessarily valued even below
what it is worth.
In order to remedy the inconvenience to which this disadvantageous exchange
must have subjected their merchants, such small states, when they began to
attend to the interest of trade, have frequently enacted, that foreign bills
of exchange of a certain value should be paid not in common currency, but
by an order upon, or by a transfer in the books of a certain bank, established
upon the credit, and under the protection of the state; this bank being always
obliged to pay, in good and true money, exactly according to the standard
of the state. The banks of Venice, Genoa, Amsterdam, Hamburg, and Nuremberg,
seem to have been all originally established with this view, though some
of them may have afterwards been made subservient to other purposes. The
money of such banks being better than the common currency of the country,
necessarily bore an agio, which was greater or smaller according as the currency
was supposed to be more or less degraded below the standard of the state.
The agio of the Bank of Hamburg, for example, which is said to be commonly
about fourteen per cent is the supposed difference between the good standard
money of the state, and the clipt, worn, and diminished currency poured into
it from all the neighbouring states.
Before 1609 the great quantity of clipt and worn foreign coin, which the
extensive trade of Amsterdam brought from all parts of Europe, reduced the
value of its currency about nine per cent below that of good money fresh
from the mint. Such money no sooner appeared than it was melted down or carried
away, as it always is in such circumstances. The merchants, with plenty of
currency, could not always find a sufficient quantity of good money to pay
their bills of exchange; and the value of those bills, in spite of several
regulations which were made to prevent it, became in a great measure uncertain.
In order to remedy these inconveniences, a bank was established in 1609
under the guarantee of the city. This bank received both foreign coin, and
the light and worn coin of the country at its real intrinsic value in the
good standard money of the country, deducting only so much as was necessary
for defraying the expense of coinage, and the other necessary expense of
management. For the value which remained, after this small deduction was
made, it gave a credit in its books. This credit was called bank money, which,
as it represented money exactly according to the standard of the mint, was
always of the same real value, and intrinsically worth more than current
money. It was at the same time enacted, that all bills drawn upon or negotiated
at Amsterdam of the value of six hundred guilders and upwards should be paid
in bank money, which at once took away all uncertainty in the value of those
bills. Every merchant, in consequence of this regulation, was obliged to
keep an account with the bank in order to pay his foreign bills of exchange,
which necessarily occasioned a certain demand for bank money.
Bank money, over and above its intrinsic superiority to currency, and the
additional value which this demand necessarily gives it, has likewise some
other advantages. It is secure from fire, robbery, and other accidents; the
city of Amsterdam is bound for it; it can be paid away by a simple transfer,
without the trouble of counting, or the risk of transporting it from one
place to another. In consequence of those different advantages, it seems
from the beginning to have borne agio, and it is generally believed that
all the money originally deposited in the bank was allowed to remain there,
nobody caring to demand payment of a debt which he could sell for a premium
in the market. By demanding payment of the bank, the owner of a bank credit
would lose this premium. As a shilling fresh from the mint will buy no more
goods in the market than one of our common worn shillings, so the good and
true money which might be brought from the coffers of the bank into those
of a private person, being mixed and confounded with the common currency
of the country, would be of no more value than that currency from which it
could no longer be readily distinguished. While it remained in the coffers
of the bank, its superiority was known and ascertained. When it had come
into those of a private person, its superiority could not well be ascertained
without more trouble than perhaps the difference was worth. By being brought
from the coffers of the bank, besides, it lost all the other advantages of
bank money; its security, its easy and safe transferability, its use in paying
foreign bills of exchange. Over and above all this, it could not be brought
from those coffers, as it will appear by and by, without previously paying
for the keeping.
Those deposits of coin, or those deposits which the bank was bound to restore
in coin, constituted the original capital of the bank, or the whole value
of what was represented by what is called bank money. At present they are
supposed to constitute but a very small part of it. In order to facilitate
the trade in bullion, the bank has been for these many years in the practice
of giving credit in its books upon deposits of gold and silver bullion. This
credit is generally about five per cent below the mint price of such bullion.
The bank grants at the same time what is called a recipe or receipt, entitling
the person who makes the deposit, or the bearer, to take out the bullion
again at any time within six months, upon re-transferring to the bank a quantity
of bank money equal to that for which credit had been given in its books
when the deposit was made, and upon paying one-fourth per cent for the keeping,
if the deposit was in silver; and one-half per cent if it was in gold; but
at the same time declaring that, in default of such payment, and upon the
expiration of this term, the deposit should belong to the bank at the price
at which it had been received, or for which credit had been given in the
transfer books. What is thus paid for the keeping of the deposit may be considered
as a sort of warehouse rent; and why this warehouse rent should be so much
dearer for gold than for silver, several different reasons have been assigned.
The fineness of gold, it has been said, is more difficult to be ascertained
than that of silver. Frauds are more easily practised, and occasion a greater
loss in the more precious metal. Silver, besides, being the standard metal,
the state, it has been said, wishes to encourage more the making of deposits
of silver than those of gold.
Deposits of bullion are most commonly made when the price is somewhat lower
than ordinary; and they are taken out again when it happens to rise. In Holland
the market price of bullion is generally above the mint price, for the same
reason that it was so in England before the late reformation of the gold
coin. The difference is said to be commonly from about six to sixteen stivers
upon the mark, or eight ounces of silver of eleven parts fine and one part
alloy. The bank price, or the credit which the bank gives for deposits of
such silver (when made in foreign coin, of which the fineness is well known
and ascertained, such as Mexico dollars), is twenty-two guilders the mark;
the mint price is about twenty-three guilders, and the market price is from
twenty-three guilders six to twenty-three guilders sixteen stivers, or from
two to three per cent above the mint price.* The proportions between the
bank price, the mint price, and the market price of gold bullion are nearly
the same. A person can generally sell his receipt for the difference between
the mint price of bullion and the market price. A receipt for bullion is
almost always worth something, and it very seldom happens, therefore, that
anybody suffers his receipt to expire, or allows his bullion to fall to the
bank at the price at which it had been received, either by not taking it
out before the end of the six months, or by neglecting to pay the one-fourth
or one-half per cent in order to obtain a new receipt for another six months.
This, however, though it happens seldom, is said to happen sometimes, and
more frequently with regard to gold than with regard to silver, on account
of the higher warehouse-rent which is paid for the keeping of the more precious
metal.
* The following are the prices at which the Bank of Amsterdam
at present (September, 1775) receives bullion and coin of
different kind:-
SILVER
Mexico dollars Guilders B-22 per mark
French crowns Guilders B-22 per mark
English silver coin Guilders B-22 per mark
Mexico dollars new coin 21 10
Ducatoons 3
Rix dollars 2 8
Bar silver containing eleven-twelfths fine silver 21 per mark,
and in this proportion down to 1/4 fine, on which 5 guilders
are given.
Fine bars, 93 per mark.
GOLD
Portugal coin B-310 per mark
Guineas B-310 per mark
Louis d'ors new B-310 per mark
Ditto old 300
New ducats 4 19 8 per ducat
Bar or ingot gold is received in proportion to its fineness compared with
the above foreign gold coin. Upon fine bars the bank gives 340 per mark.
In general, however, something more is given upon coin of a known fineness,
than upon gold and silver bars, of which the fineness cannot be ascertained
but by a process of melting and assaying.
The person who by making a deposit of bullion obtains both a bank credit
and receipt, pays his bills of exchange as they become due with his bank
credit; and either sells or keeps his receipt according as he judges that
the price of bullion is likely to rise or to fall. The receipt and the bank
credit seldom keep long together, and there is no occasion that they should.
The person who has a receipt, and who wants to take out bullion, finds always
plenty of bank credits, or bank money to buy at the ordinary price; and the
person who has bank money, and wants to take out bullion, finds receipts
always in equal abundance.
The owners of bank credits, and the holders of receipts, constitute two
different sorts of creditors against the bank. The holder of a receipt cannot
draw out the bullion for which it is granted, without reassigning to the
bank a sum of bank money equal to the price at which the bullion had been
received. If he has no bank money of his own, he must purchase it of those
who have it. The owner of bank money cannot draw out bullion without producing
to the bank receipts for the quantity which he wants. If he has none of his
own, he must buy them of those who have them. The holder of a receipt, when
he purchases bank money, purchases the power of taking out a quantity of
bullion, of which the mint price is five per cent above the bank price. The
agio of five per cent therefore, which he commonly pays for it, is paid not
for an imaginary but for a real value. The owner of bank money, when he purchases
a receipt, purchases the power of taking out a quantity of bullion of which
the market price is commonly from two to three per cent above the mint price.
The price which he pays for it, therefore, is paid likewise for a real value.
The price of the receipt, and the price of the bank money, compound or make
up between them the full value or price of the bullion.
Upon deposits of the coin current in the country, the bank grants receipts
likewise as well as bank credits; but those receipts are frequently of no
value, and will bring no price in the market. Upon ducatoons, for example,
which in the currency pass for three guilders three stivers each, the bank
gives a credit of three guilders only, or five per cent below their current
value. It grants a receipt likewise entitling the bearer to take out the
number of ducatoons deposited at any time within six months, upon paying
one-fourth per cent for the keeping. This receipt will frequently bring no
price in the market. Three guilders bank money generally sell in the market
for three guilders three stivers, the full value of the ducatoons, if they
were taken out of the bank; and before they can be taken out, one-fourth
per cent must be paid for the keeping, which would be mere loss to the holder
of the receipt. If the agio of the bank, however, should at any time fall
to three per cent such receipts might bring some price in the market, and
might sell for one and three-fourths per cent. But the agio of the bank being
now generally about five per cent such receipts are frequently allowed to
expire, or as they express it, to fall to the bank. The receipts which are
given for deposits of gold ducats fall to it yet more frequently, because
a higher warehouse-rent, or one-half per cent must be paid for the keeping
of them before they can be taken out again. The five per cent which the bank
gains, when deposits either of coin or bullion are allowed to fall to it,
may be considered as the warehouse-rent for the perpetual keeping of such
deposits.
The sum of bank money for which the receipts are expired must be very considerable.
It must comprehend the whole original capital of the bank, which, it is generally
supposed, has been allowed to remain there from the time it was first deposited,
nobody caring either to renew his receipt or to take out his deposit, as,
for the reasons already assigned, neither the one nor the other could be
done without loss. But whatever may be the amount of this sum, the proportion
which it bears to the whole mass of bank money is supposed to be very small.
The Bank of Amsterdam has for these many years past been the great warehouse
of Europe for bullion, for which the receipts are very seldom allowed to
expire, or, as they express it, to fall to the bank. far greater part of
the bank money, or of the credits upon the books of the bank, is supposed
to have been created, for these many years past, by such deposits which the
dealers in bullion are continually both making and withdrawing.
No demand can be made upon the bank but by means of a recipe or receipt.
The smaller mass of bank money, for which the receipts are expired, is mixed
and confounded with the much greater mass for which they are still in force;
so that, though there may be a considerable sum of bank money for which there
are no receipts, there is no specific sum or portion of it which may not
at any time be demanded by one. The bank cannot be debtor to two persons
for the same thing; and the owner of bank money who has no receipt cannot
demand payment of the bank till he buys one. In ordinary and quiet times,
he can find no difficulty in getting one to buy at the market price, which
generally corresponds with the price at which he can sell the coin or bullion
it entities him to take out of the bank.
It might be otherwise during a public calamity; an invasion, for example,
such as that of the French in 1672. The owners of bank money being then all
eager to draw it out of the bank, in order to have it their own keeping,
the demand for receipts might raise their price to an exorbitant height.
The holders of them might form expectations, and, instead of two or three
per cent, demand half the bank money for which credit had been given upon
the deposits that the receipts had respectively been granted for. The enemy,
informed of the constitution of the bank, might even buy them up, in order
to prevent the carrying away of the treasure. In such emergencies, the bank,
it is supposed, would break through its ordinary rule of making payment only
to the holders of receipts. The holders of receipts, who had no bank money,
must have received within two or three per cent of the value of the deposit
for which their respective receipts had been granted. The bank, therefore,
it is said, would in this case make no scruple of paying, either with money
or bullion, the full value of what the owners of bank money who could get
no receipts were credited for in its books; paying at the same time two or
three per cent to such holders of receipts as had no bank money, that being
the whole value which in this state of things could justly be supposed due
to them.
Even in ordinary and quiet times it is the interest of the holders of receipts
to depress the agio, in order either to buy bank money (and consequently
the bullion, which their receipts would then enable them to take out of the
bank) so much cheaper, or to sell their receipts to those who have bank money,
and who want to take out bullion, so much dearer; the price of a receipt
being generally equal to the difference between the market price of bank
money, and that of the coin or bullion for which the receipt had been granted.
It is the interest of the owners of bank money, on the contrary, to raise
the agio, in order either to sell their bank money so much dearer, or to
buy a receipt so much cheaper. To prevent the stock-jobbing tricks which
those opposite interests might sometimes occasion, the bank has of late years
come to the resolution to sell at all times bank money for currency, at five
per cent agio, and to buy it in again at four per cent agio. In consequence
of this resolution, the agio can never either rise above five or sink below
four per cent, and the proportion between the market price of bank and that
of current money is kept at all times very near to the proportion between
their intrinsic values. Before this resolution was taken, the market price
of bank money used sometimes to rise so high as nine per cent agio, and sometimes
to sink so low as par, according as opposite interests happened to influence
the market.
The Bank of Amsterdam professes to lend out no part of what is deposited
with it, but, for every guilder for which it gives credit in its books, to
keep in its repositories the value of a guilder either in money or bullion.
That it keeps in its repositories all the money or bullion for which there
are receipts in force, for which it is at all times liable to be called upon,
and which, in reality, is continually going from it and returning to it again,
cannot well be doubted. But whether it does so likewise with regard to that
part of its capital, for which the receipts are long ago expired, for which
in ordinary and quiet times it cannot be called upon, and which in reality
is very likely to remain with it for ever, or as long as the States of the
United Provinces subsist, may perhaps appear more uncertain. At Amsterdam,
however, no point of faith is better established than that for every guilder,
circulated as bank money, there is a correspondent guilder in gold or silver
to be found in the treasure of the bank. The city is guarantee that it should
be so. The bank is under the direction of the four reigning burgomasters
who are changed every year. Each new set of burgomasters visits the treasure,
compares it with the books, receives it upon oath, and delivers it over,
with the same awful solemnity, to the set which succeeds; and in that sober
and religious country oaths are not yet disregarded. A rotation of this kind
seems alone a sufficient security against any practices which cannot be avowed.
Amidst all the revolutions which faction has ever occasioned in the government
of Amsterdam, the prevailing party has at no time accused their predecessors
of infidelity in the administration of the bank. No accusation could have
affected more deeply the reputation and fortune of the disgraced party, and
if such an accusation could have been supported, we may be assured that it
would have been brought. In 1672, when the French king was at Utrecht, the
Bank of Amsterdam paid so readily as left no doubt of the fidelity with which
it had observed its engagements. Some of the pieces which were then brought
from its repositories appeared to have been scorched with the fire which
happened in the town-house soon after the bank was established. Those pieces,
therefore, must have lain there from that time.
What may be the amount of the treasure in the bank is a question which has
long employed speculations of the curious. Nothing but conjecture can be
offered concerning it. It is generally reckoned that there are about two
thousand people who keep accounts with the bank, and allowing them to have,
one with another, the value of fifteen hundred pounds sterling lying upon
their respective accounts (a very large allowance), the whole quantity of
bank money, and consequently of treasure in the bank, will amount to about
three millions sterling, or, at eleven guilders the pound sterling, thirty-three
millions of guilders- a great sum, and sufficient to carry on a very extensive
circulation, but vastly below the extravagant ideas which some people have
formed of this treasure.
The city of Amsterdam derives a considerable revenue from the bank. Besides
what may be called the warehouse-rent above mentioned, each person, upon
first opening an account with the bank, pays a fee of ten guilders; and for
every new account three guilders three stivers; for every transfer two stivers;
and if the transfer is for less than three hundred guilders, six stivers,
in order to discourage the multiplicity of small transactions. The person
who neglects to balance his account twice in the year forfeits twenty-five
guilders. The person who orders a transfer for more than is upon his account,
is obliged to pay three per cent for the sum overdrawn, and his order is
set aside into the bargain. The bank is supposed, too, to make a considerable
profit by the sale of the foreign coin or bullion which sometimes falls to
it by the expiring of receipts, and which is always kept till it can be sold
with advantage. It makes a profit likewise by selling bank money at five
per cent agio, and buying it in at four. These different emoluments amount
to a good deal more than what is necessary for paying the salaries of officers,
and defraying the expense of management. What is paid for the keeping of
bullion upon receipts is alone supposed to amount to a neat annual revenue
of between one hundred and fifty thousand and two hundred thousand guilders.
Public utility, however, and not revenue, was the original object of this
institution. Its object was to relieve the merchants from the inconvenience
of a disadvantageous exchange. The revenue which has arisen from it was unforeseen,
and may be considered as accidental. But it is now time to return from this
long digression, into which I have been insensibly led in endeavouring to
explain the reasons why the exchange between the countries which pay in what
is called bank money, and those which pay in common currency, should generally
appear to be in favour of the former and against the latter. The former pay
in a species of money of which the intrinsic value is always the same, and
exactly agreeable to the standard of their respective mints; the latter is
a species of money of which the intrinsic value is continually varying, and
is almost always more or less below that standard.
Part
2: Of the Unreasonableness of those
extraordinary Restraints upon other
Principles
In the foregoing part of this chapter I have endeavoured to show, even upon
the principles of the commercial system, how unnecessary it is to lay extraordinary
restraints upon the importation of goods from those countries with which the
balance of trade is supposed to be disadvantageous.
Nothing, however, can be more absurd than this whole doctrine of the balance
of trade, upon which, not only these restraints, but almost all the other
regulations of commerce are founded. When two places trade with one another,
this doctrine supposes that, if the balance be even, neither of them either
loses or gains; but if it leans in any degree to one side, that one of them
loses and the other gains in proportion to its declension from the exact
equilibrium. Both suppositions are false. A trade which is forced by means
of bounties and monopolies may be and commonly is disadvantageous to the
country in whose favour it is meant to be established, as I shall endeavour
to show hereafter. But that trade which, without force or constraint, is
naturally and regularly carried on between any two places is always advantageous,
though not always equally so, to both.
By advantage or gain, I understand not the increase of the quantity of gold
and silver, but that of the exchangeable value of the annual produce of the
land and labour of the country, or the increase of the annual revenue of
its inhabitants.
If the balance be even, and if the trade between the two places consist
altogether in the exchange of their native commodities, they will, upon most
occasions, not only both gain, but they will gain equally, or very near equally;
each will in this case afford a market for a part of the surplus produce
of the other; each will replace a capital which had been employed in raising
and preparing for the market this part of the surplus produce of the other,
and which had been distributed among, and given revenue and maintenance to
a certain number of its inhabitants. Some part of the inhabitants of each,
therefore, will indirectly derive their revenue and maintenance from the
other. As the commodities exchanged, too, are supposed to be of equal value,
so the two capitals employed in the trade will, upon most occasions, be equal,
or very nearly equal; and both being employed in raising the native commodities
of the two countries, the revenue and maintenance which their distribution
will afford to the inhabitants of each will be equal, or very nearly equal.
This revenue and maintenance, thus mutually afforded, will be greater or
smaller in proportion to the extent of their dealings. If these should annually
amount to an hundred thousand pounds, for example, or to a million on each
side, each of them would afford an annual revenue in the one case of an hundred
thousand pounds, in the other of a million, to the inhabitants of the other.
If their trade should be of such a nature that one of them exported to the
other nothing but native commodities, while the returns of that other consisted
altogether in foreign goods; the balance, in this case, would still be supposed
even, commodities being paid for with commodities. They would, in this case
too, both gain, but they would not gain equally; and the inhabitants of the
country which exported nothing but native commodities would derive the greatest
revenue from the trade. If England, for example, should import from France
nothing but the native commodities of that country, and, not having such
commodities of its own as were in demand there, should annually repay them
by sending thither a large quantity of foreign goods, tobacco, we shall suppose,
and East India goods; this trade, though it would give some revenue to the
inhabitants of both countries, would give more to those of France than to
those of England. The whole French capital annually employed in it would
annually be distributed among the people of France. But that part of the
English capital only which was employed in producing the English commodities
with which those foreign goods were purchased would be annually distributed
among the people of England. The greater part of it would replace the capitals
which had been employed in Virginia, Indostan, and China, and which had given
revenue and maintenance to the of those distant countries. If the capitals
were equal, or nearly equal, therefore this employment of the French capital
would augment much more the revenue of the people of France than that of
the English capital would the revenue of the people of England. France would
in this case carry on a direct foreign trade of consumption with England;
whereas England would carry on a round-about trade of the same kind with
France. The different effects of a capital employed in the direct and of
one employed in the round-about foreign trade of consumption have already
been fully explained.
There is not, probably, between any two countries a trade which consists
altogether in the exchange either of native commodities on both sides, or
of native commodities on one side and of foreign goods on the other. Almost
all countries exchange with one another partly native and partly foreign
goods. That country, however, in whose cargoes there is the greatest proportion
of native, and the least of foreign goods, will always be the principal gainer.
If it was not with tobacco and East India goods, but with gold and silver,
that England paid for the commodities annually imported from France, the
balance, in this case, would be supposed uneven, commodities not being paid
for with commodities, but with gold and silver. The trade, however, would,
in this case, as in the foregoing, give some revenue to the inhabitants of
both countries, but more to those of France than to those of England. It
would give some revenue to those of England. The capital which had been employed
in producing the English goods that purchased this gold and silver, the capital
which had been distributed among, and given revenue to, certain inhabitants
of England, would thereby be replaced and enabled to continue that employment.
The whole capital of England would no more be diminished by this exportation
of gold and silver than by the exportation of an equal value of any other
goods. On the contrary, it would in most cases be augmented. No goods are
sent abroad but those for which the demand is supposed to be greater abroad
than at home, and of which the returns consequently, it is expected, will
be of more value at home than the commodities exported. If the tobacco which,
in England, is worth only a hundred thousand pounds, when sent to France
will purchase wine which is, in England, worth a hundred and ten thousand,
this exchange will equally augment the capital of England by ten thousand
pounds. If a hundred thousand pounds of English gold, in the same manner,
purchase French wine which, in England, is worth a hundred and ten thousand,
this exchange will equally augment the capital of England by ten thousand
pounds. As a merchant who has a hundred and ten thousand pounds worth of
wine in his cellar is a richer man than he who has only a hundred thousand
pounds worth of tobacco in his warehouse, so is he likewise a richer man
than he who has only a hundred thousand pounds worth of gold in his coffers.
He can put into motion a greater quantity of industry, and give revenue,
maintenance, and employment to a greater number of people than either of
the other two. But the capital of the country is equal to the capitals of
all its different inhabitants, and the quantity of industry which can be
annually maintained in it is equal to what all those different capitals can
maintain. Both the capital of the country, therefore, and the quantity of
industry which can be annually maintained in it, must generally be augmented
by this exchange. It would, indeed, be more advantageous for England that
it could purchase the wines of France with its own hardware and broadcloth
than with either the tobacco of Virginia or the gold and silver of Brazil
and Peru. A direct foreign trade of consumption is always more advantageous
than a roundabout one. But a round-about foreign trade of consumption, which
is carried on with gold and silver, does not seem to be less advantageous
than any other equally round-about one. Neither is a country which has no
mines more likely to be exhausted of gold and silver by this annual exportation
of those metals than one which does not grow tobacco by the like annual exportation
of that plant. As a country which has wherewithal to buy tobacco will never
be long in want of it, so neither will one be long in want of gold and silver
which has wherewithal to purchase those metals.
It is a losing trade, it is said, which a workman carries on with the alehouse;
and the trade which a manufacturing nation would naturally carry on with
a wine country may be considered as a trade of the same nature. I answer,
that the trade with the alehouse is not necessarily a losing trade. In
its own nature it is just as advantageous as any other, though perhaps somewhat
more liable to be abused. The employment of a brewer, and even that of
a
retailer of fermented liquors, are as necessary divisions of labour as
any other. It will generally be more advantageous for a workman to buy of
the
brewer the quantity he has occasion for than to brew it himself, and if
he is a poor workman, it will generally be more advantageous for him to buy
it by little and little of the retailer than a large quantity of the brewer.
He may no doubt buy too much of either, as he may of any other dealers
in
his neighbourhood, of the butcher, if he is a glutton, or of the draper,
if he affects to be a beau among his companions. It is advantageous to
the great body of workmen, notwithstanding, that all these trades should
be free,
though this freedom may be abused in all of them, and is more likely to
be so, perhaps, in some than in others. Though individuals, besides, may
sometimes
ruin their fortunes by an excessive consumption of fermented liquors, there
seems to be no risk that a nation should do so. Though in every country
there are many people who spend upon such liquors more than they can afford,
there
are always many more who spend less. It deserves to be remarked too, that,
if we consult experience, the cheapness of wine seems to be a cause, not
of drunkenness, but of sobriety. The inhabitants of the wine countries
are in general the soberest people in Europe; witness the Spainards, the
Italians,
and the inhabitants of the southern provinces of France. People are seldom
guilty of excess in what is their daily fare. Nobody affects the character
of liberality and good fellowship by being profuse of a liquor which is
as cheap as small beer. On the contrary, in the countries which, either from
excessive heat or cold, produce no grapes, and where wine consequently
is
dear and a rarity, drunkenness is a common vice, as among the northern
nations, and all those who live between the tropics, the negroes, for example,
on
the coast of Guinea. When a French regiment comes from some of the northern
provinces of France, where wine is somewhat dear, to be quartered in the
southern, where it is very cheap, the soldiers, I have frequently heard
it observed are at first debauched by the cheapness and novelty of good wine;
but after a few months' residence, the greater part of them become as sober
as the rest of the inhabitants. Were the duties upon foreign wines, and
the
excises upon malt, beer, and ale to be taken away all at once, it might,
in the same manner, occasion in Great Britain a pretty general and temporary
drunkenness among the middling and inferior ranks of people, which would
probably be soon followed by a permanent and almost universal sobriety.
At present drunkenness is by no means the vice of people of fashion, or of
those
who can easily afford the most expensive liquors. A gentleman drunk with
ale has scarce ever been seen among us. The restraints upon the wine trade
in Great Britain, besides, do not so much seem calculated to hinder the
people from going, if I may say so, to the alehouse, as from going where
they can
buy the best and cheapest liquor. They favour the wine trade of Portugal,
and discourage that of France. The Portugese, it is said, indeed, are better
customers for our manufactures than the French, and should therefore be
encouraged in preference to them. As they give us their custom, it is pretended,
we
should give them ours. The sneaking arts of underling tradesmen are thus
erected into political maxims for the conduct of a great empire: for it
is the most underling tradesmen only who make it a rule to employ chiefly
their
own customers. A great trader purchases his goods always where they are
cheapest and best, without regard to any little interest of this kind.
By such maxims as these, however, nations have been taught that their interest
consisted in beggaring all their neighbours. Each nation has been made to
look with an invidious eye upon the prosperity of all the nations with which
it trades, and to consider their gain as its own loss. Commerce, which ought
naturally to be, among nations, as among individuals, a bond of union and
friendship, has become the most fertile source of discord and animosity.
The capricious ambition of kings and ministers has not, during the present
and the preceding century, been more fatal to the repose of Europe than the
impertinent jealousy of merchants and manufacturers. The violence and injustice
of the rulers of mankind is an ancient evil, for which, I am afraid, the
nature of human affairs can scarce admit of a remedy. But the mean rapacity,
the monopolizing spirit of merchants and manufacturers, who neither are,
nor ought to be, the rulers of mankind, though it cannot perhaps be corrected
may very easily be prevented from disturbing the tranquillity of anybody
but themselves.
That it was the spirit of monopoly which originally both invented and propagated
this doctrine cannot be doubted; and they who first taught it were by no
means such fools as they who believed it. In every country it always is and
must be the interest of the great body of the people to buy whatever they
want of those who sell it cheapest. The proposition is so very manifest that
it seems ridiculous to take any pains to prove it; nor could it ever have
been called in question had not the interested sophistry of merchants and
manufacturers confounded the common sense of mankind. Their interest is,
in this respect, directly opposite to that of the great body of the people.
As it is the interest of the freemen of a corporation to hinder the rest
of the inhabitants from employing any workmen but themselves, so it is the
interest of the merchants and manufacturers of every country to secure to
themselves the monopoly of the home market. Hence in Great Britain, and in
most other European countries, the extraordinary duties upon almost all goods
imported by alien merchants. Hence the high duties and prohibitions upon
all those foreign manufactures which can come into competition with our own.
Hence, too, the extraordinary restraints upon the importation of almost all
sorts of goods from those countries with which the balance of trade is supposed
to be disadvantageous; that is, from those against whom national animosity
happens to be most violently inflamed.
The wealth of a neighbouring nation, however, though dangerous in war and
politics, is certainly advantageous in trade. In a state of hostility it
may enable our enemies to maintain fleets and armies superior to our own;
but in a state of peace and commerce it must likewise enable them to exchange
with us to a greater value, and to afford a better market, either for the
immediate produce of our own industry, or for whatever is purchased with
that produce. As a rich man is likely to be a better customer to the industrious
people in his neighbourhood than a poor, so is likewise a rich nation. A
rich man, indeed, who is himself a manufacturer, is a very dangerous neighbour
to all those who deal in the same way. All the rest of the neighbourhood,
however, by far the greatest number, profit by the good market which his
expense affords them. They even profit by his underselling the poorer workmen
who deal in the same way with him. The manufacturers of a rich nation, in
the same manner, may no doubt be very dangerous rivals to those of their
neighbours. This very competition, however, is advantageous to the great
body of the people, who profit greatly besides by the good market which the
great expense of such a nation affords them in every other way. Private people
who want to make a fortune never think of retiring to the remote and poor
provinces of the country, but resort either to the capital, or to some of
the great commercial towns. They know that where little wealth circulates
there is little to be got, but that where a great deal is in motion, some
share of it may fall to them. The same maxims which would in this manner
direct the common sense of one, or ten, or twenty individuals, should regulate
the judgment of one, or ten, or twenty millions, and should make a whole
nation regard the riches of its neighbours as a probable cause and occasion
for itself to acquire riches. A nation that would enrich itself by foreign
trade is certainly most likely to do so when its neighbours are all rich,
industrious, and commercial nations. A great nation surrounded on all sides
by wandering savages and poor barbarians might, no doubt, acquire riches
by the cultivation of its own lands, and by its own interior commerce, but
not by foreign trade. It seems to have been in this manner that the ancient
Egyptians and the modern Chinese acquired their great wealth. The ancient
Egyptians, it is said, neglected foreign commerce, and the modern Chinese,
it is known, bold it in the utmost contempt, and scarce deign to afford it
the decent protection of the laws. The modern maxims of foreign commerce,
by aiming at the impoverishment of all our neighbours, so far as they are
capable of producing their intended effect, tend to render that very commerce
insignificant and contemptible.
It is in consequence of these maxims that the commerce between France and
England has in both countries been subjected to so many discouragements and
restraints. If those two countries, however, were to consider their real
interest, without either mercantile jealousy or national animosity, the commerce
of France might be more advantageous to Great Britain than that of any other
country, and for the same reason that of Great Britain to France. France
is the nearest neighbour to Great Britain. In the trade between the southern
coast of England and the northern and north-western coasts of France, the
returns might be expected, in the same manner as in the inland trade, four,
five, or six times in the year. The capital, therefore, employed in this
trade could in each of the two countries keep in motion four, five, or six
times the quantity of industry, and afford employment and subsistence to
four, five, or six times the number of people, which an equal capital could
do in the greater part of the other branches of foreign trade. Between the
parts of France and Great Britain most remote from one another, the returns
might be expected, at least, once in the year, and even this trade would
so far be at least equally advantageous as the greater part of the other
branches of our foreign European trade. It would be, at least, three times
more advantageous than the boasted trade with our North American colonies,
in which the returns were seldom made in less than three years, frequently
not in less than four or five years. France, besides, is supposed to contain
twenty-four millions of inhabitants. Our North American colonies were never
supposed to contain more than three millions; and France is a much richer
country than North America; though, on account of the more unequal distribution
of riches, there is much more poverty and beggary in the one country than
in the other. France, therefore, could afford a market at least eight times
more extensive, and, on account of the superior frequency of the returns,
four-and-twenty times more advantageous than that which our North American
colonies ever afforded. The trade of Great Britain would be just as advantageous
to France, and, in proportion to the wealth, population, and proximity of
the respective countries, would have the same superiority over that which
France carries on with her own colonies. Such is the very great difference
between that trade, which the wisdom of both nations has thought proper to
discourage, and that which it has favoured the most.
But the very same circumstances which would have rendered an open and free
commerce between the two countries so advantageous to both, have occasioned
the principal obstructions to that commerce. Being neighbours, they are necessarily
enemies, and the wealth and power of each becomes, upon that account, more
formidable to the other; and what would increase the advantage of national
friendship serves only to inflame the violence of national animosity. They
are both rich and industrious nations; and the merchants and manufacturers
of each dread the competition of the skill and activity of those of the other.
Mercantile jealousy is excited, and both inflames, and is itself inflamed,
by the violence of national animosity; and the traders of both countries
have announced, with all the passionate confidence of interested falsehood,
the certain ruin of each, in consequence of that unfavourable balance of
trade, which, they pretend, would be the infallible effect of an unrestrained
commerce with the other.
There is no commercial country in Europe of which the approaching ruin has
not frequently been foretold by the pretended doctors of this system from
an unfavourable balance of trade. After all the anxiety, however, which they
have excited about this, after all the vain attempts of almost all trading
nations to turn that balance in their own favour and against their neighbours,
it does not appear that any one nation in Europe has been in any respect
impoverished by this cause. Every town and country, on the contrary, in proportion
as they have opened their ports to all nations, instead of being ruined by
this free trade, as the principles of the commercial system would lead us
to expect, have been enriched by it. Though there are in Europe, indeed,
a few towns which in some respects deserve the name of free ports, there
is no country which does so. Holland, perhaps, approaches the nearest to
this character of any though still very remote from it; and Holland, it is
acknowledged, not only derives its whole wealth, but a great part of its
necessary subsistence, from foreign trade.
There is another balance, indeed, which has already been explained, very
different from the balance of trade, and which, according as it happens to
be either favourable or unfavourable, necessarily occasions the prosperity
or decay of every nation. This is the balance of the annual produce and consumption.
If the exchangeable value of the annual produce, it has already been observed,
exceeds that of the annual consumption, the capital of the society must annually
increase in proportion to this excess. The society in this case lives within
its revenue, and what is annually saved out of its revenue is naturally added
to its capital, and employed so as to increase still further the annual produce.
If the exchangeable value of the annual produce, on the contrary, fail short
of the annual consumption, the capital of the society must annually decay
in proportion to this deficiency. The expense of the society in this case
exceeds its revenue, and necessarily encroaches upon its capital. Its capital,
therefore, must necessarily decay, and together with it the exchangeable
value of the annual produce of its industry.
This balance of produce and consumption is entirely different from what
is called the balance of trade. It might take place in a nation which had
no foreign trade, but which was entirely separated from all the world. It
may take place in the whole globe of the earth, of which the wealth, population,
and improvement may be either gradually increasing or gradually decaying.
The balance of produce and consumption may be constantly in favour of a
nation, though what is called the balance of trade be generally against it.
A nation may import to a greater value than it exports for half a century,
perhaps, together; the gold and silver which comes into it during an this
time may be all immediately sent out of it; its circulating coin may gradually
decay, different sorts of paper money being substituted in its place, and
even the debts, too, which it contracts in the principal nations with whom
it deals, may be gradually increasing; and yet its real wealth, the exchangeable
value of the annual produce of its lands and labour, may, during the same
period, have been increasing in a much greater proportion. The state of our
North American colonies, and of the trade which they carried on with Great
Britain, before the commencement of the present disturbances, may serve as
a proof that this is by no means an impossible supposition.
...
..
..
CLICK
HERE TO DISCUSS THIS BOOK
|
|