The
whole of the advantages and disadvantages of the different
employments of labour and stock must, in the same neighbourhood,
be either perfectly equal or continually tending to equality.
If in the same neighbourhood, there was any employment evidently
either more or less advantageous than the rest, so many people
would crowd into it in the one case, and so many would desert
it in the other, that its advantages would soon return to
the level of other employments. This at least would be the
case in a society where things were left to follow their natural
course, where there was perfect liberty, and where every man
was perfectly free both to choose what occupation he thought
proper, and to change it as often as he thought proper. Every
man's interest would prompt him to seek the advantageous,
and to shun the disadvantageous employment.
Pecuniary
wages and profit, indeed, are everywhere in Europe extremely
different according to the different employments of labour
and stock. But this difference arises partly from certain
circumstances in the employments themselves, which, either
really, or at least in the imaginations of men, make up for
a small pecuniary gain in some, and counterbalance a great
one in others; and partly from the policy of Europe, which
nowhere leaves things at perfect liberty.
The
particular consideration of those circumstances and of that
policy will divide this chapter into two parts.
Part
1: Inequalities arising from the Nature of the Employments
themselves
The
five following are the principal circumstances which, so far
as I have been able to observe, make up for a small pecuniary
gain in some employments, and counterbalance a great one in
others: first, the agreeableness or disagreeableness of the
employments themselves; secondly, the easiness and cheapness,
or the difficulty and expense of learning them; thirdly, the
constancy or inconstancy of employment in them; fourthly,
the small or great trust which must be reposed in those who
exercise them; and, fifthly, the probability or improbability
of success in them.
First,
the wages of labour vary with the ease or hardship, the cleanliness
or dirtiness, the honourableness or dishonourableness of the
employment. Thus in most places, take the year round, a journeyman
tailor earns less than a journeyman weaver. His work is much
easier. A journeyman weaver earns less than a journeyman smith.
His work is not always easier, but it is much cleanlier. A
journeyman blacksmith, though an artificer, seldom earns so
much in twelve hours as a collier, who is only a labourer,
does in eight. His work is not quite so dirty, is less dangerous,
and is carried on in daylight, and above ground. Honour makes
a great part of the reward of all honourable professions.
In point of pecuniary gain, all things considered, they are
generally under-recompensed, as I shall endeavour to show
by and by. Disgrace has the contrary effect. The trade of
a butcher is a brutal and an odious business; but it is in
most places more profitable than the greater part of common
trades. The most detestable of all employments, that of public
executioner, is, in proportion to the quantity of work done,
better paid than any common trade whatever.
Hunting
and fishing, the most important employments of mankind in
the rude state of society, become in its advanced state their
most agreeable amusements, and they pursue for pleasure what
they once followed from necessity. In the advanced state of
society, therefore, they are all very poor people who follow
as a trade what other people pursue as a pastime. Fishermen
have been so since the time of Theocritus. A poacher is everywhere
a very poor man in Great Britain. In countries where the rigour
of the law suffers no poachers, the licensed hunter is not
in a much better condition. The natural taste for those employments
makes more people follow them than can live comfortably by
them, and the produce of their labour, in proportion to its
quantity, comes always too cheap to market to afford anything
but the most scanty subsistence to the labourers.
Disagreeableness
and disgrace affect the profits of stock in the same manner
as the wages of labour. The keeper of an inn or tavern, who
is never master of his own house, and who is exposed to the
brutality of every drunkard, exercises neither a very agreeable
nor a very creditable business. But there is scarce any common
trade in which a small stock yields so great a profit.
Secondly,
the wages of labour vary with the easiness and cheapness,
or the difficulty and expense of learning the business.
When
any expensive machine is erected, the extraordinary work to
be performed by it before it is worn out, it must be expected,
will replace the capital laid out upon it, with at least the
ordinary profits. A man educated at the expense of much labour
and time to any of those employments which require extraordinary
dexterity and skill, may be compared to one of those expensive
machines. The work which he learns to perform, it must be
expected, over and above the usual wages of common labour,
will replace to him the whole expense of his education, with
at least the ordinary profits of an equally valuable capital.
It must do this, too, in a reasonable time, regard being had
to the very uncertain duration of human life, in the same
manner as to the more certain duration of the machine.
The
difference between the wages of skilled labour and those of
common labour is founded upon this principle.
The
policy of Europe considers the labour of all mechanics, artificers,
and manufacturers, as skilled labour; and that of all country
labourers as common labour. It seems to suppose that of the
former to be of a more nice and delicate nature than that
of the latter. It is so perhaps in some cases; but in the
greater part is it quite otherwise, as I shall endeavour to
show by and by. The laws and customs of Europe, therefore,
in order to qualify any person for exercising the one species
of labour, impose the necessity of an apprenticeship, though
with different degrees of rigour in different places. They
leave the other free and open to everybody. During the continuance
of the apprenticeship, the whole labour of the apprentice
belongs to his master. In the meantime he must, in many cases,
be maintained by his parents or relations, and in almost all
cases must be clothed by them. Some money, too, is commonly
given to the master for teaching him his trade. They who cannot
give money give time, or become bound for more than the usual
number of years; a consideration which, though it is not always
advantageous to the master, on account of the usual idleness
of apprentices, is always disadvantageous to the apprentice.
In country labour, on the contrary, the labourer, while he
is employed about the easier, learns the more difficult parts
of his business, and his own labour maintains him through
all the different stages of his employment. It is reasonable,
therefore, that in Europe the wages of mechanics, artificers,
and manufacturers, should be somewhat higher than those of
common labourers. They are so accordingly, and their superior
gains make them in most places be considered as a superior
rank of people. This superiority, however, is generally very
small; the daily or weekly earnings of journeymen in the more
common sorts of manufactures, such as those of plain linen
and woollen cloth, computed at an average, are, in most places,
very little more than the day wages of common labourers. Their
employment, indeed, is more steady and uniform, and the superiority
of their earnings, taking the whole year together, may be
somewhat greater. It seems evidently, however, to be no greater
than what is sufficient to compensate the superior expense
of their education.
Education
in the ingenious arts and in the liberal professions is still
more tedious and expensive. The pecuniary recompense, therefore,
of painters and sculptors, of lawyers and physicians, ought
to be much more liberal; and it is so accordingly.
The
profits of stock seem to be very little affected by the easiness
or difficulty of learning the trade in which it is employed.
All the different ways in which stock is commonly employed
in great towns seem, in reality, to be almost equally easy
and equally difficult to learn. One branch either of foreign
or domestic trade cannot well be a much more intricate business
than another.
Thirdly,
the wages of labour in different occupations vary with the
constancy or inconstancy of employment.
Employment
is much more constant in some trades than in others. In the
greater part of manufacturers, a journeyman may be pretty
sure of employment almost every day in the year that he is
able to work. A mason or bricklayer, on the contrary, can
work neither in hard frost nor in foul weather, and his employment
at all other times depends upon the occasional calls of his
customers. He is liable, in consequence, to be frequently
without any. What he earns, therefore, while he is employed,
must not only maintain him while he is idle, but make him
some compensation for those anxious and desponding moments
which the thought of so precarious a situation must sometimes
occasion. Where the computed earnings of the greater part
of manufacturers, accordingly, are nearly upon a level with
the day wages of common labourers, those of masons and bricklayers
are generally from one half more to double those wages. Where
common labourers earn four and five shillings a week, masons
and bricklayers frequently earn seven and eight; where the
former earn six, the latter often earn nine and ten; and where
the former earn nine and ten, as in London, the latter commonly
earn fifteen and eighteen. No species of skilled labour, however,
seems more easy to learn than that of masons and bricklayers.
Chairmen in London, during the summer season, are said sometimes
to be employed as bricklayers. The high wages of those workmen,
therefore, are not so much the recompense of their skill,
as the compensation for the inconstancy of their employment.
A
house carpenter seems to exercise rather a nicer and more
ingenious trade than a mason. In most places, however, for
it is not universally so, his day-wages are somewhat lower.
His employment, though it depends much, does not depend so
entirely upon the occasional calls of his customers; and it
is not liable to be interrupted by the weather.
When
the trades which generally afford constant employment happen
in a particular place not to do so, the wages of the workmen
always rise a good deal above their ordinary proportion to
those of common labour. In London almost all journeymen artificers
are liable to be called upon and dismissed by their masters
from day to day, and from week to week, in the same manner
as day-labourers in other places. The lowest order of artificers,
journeymen tailors, accordingly, earn there half a crown a-day,
though eighteenpence may be reckoned the wages of common labour.
In small towns and country villages, the wages of journeymen
tailors frequently scarce equal those of common labour; but
in London they are often many weeks without employment, particularly
during the summer.
When
the inconstancy of employment is combined with the hardship,
disagreeableness and dirtiness of the work, it sometimes raises
the wages of the most common labour above those of the most
skilful artificers. A collier working by the piece is supposed,
at Newcastle, to earn commonly about double, and in many parts
of Scotland about three times the wages of common labour.
His high wages arise altogether from the hardship, disagreeableness,
and dirtiness of his work. His employment may, upon most occasions,
be as constant as he pleases. The coal-heavers in London exercise
a trade which in hardship, dirtiness, and disagreeableness,
almost equals that of colliers; and from the unavoidable irregularity
in the arrivals of coal-ships, the employment of the greater
part of them is necessarily very inconstant. If colliers,
therefore, commonly earn double and triple the wages of common
labour, it ought not to seem unreasonable that coal-heavers
should sometimes earn four and five times those wages. In
the inquiry made into their condition a few years ago, it
was found that at the rate at which they were then paid, they
could earn from six to ten shillings a day. Six shillings
are about four times the wages of common labour in London,
and in every particular trade the lowest common earnings may
always be considered as those of the far greater number. How
extravagant soever those earnings may appear, if they were
more than sufficient to compensate all the disagreeable circumstances
of the business, there would soon be so great a number of
competitors as, in a trade which has no exclusive privilege,
would quickly reduce them to a lower rate.
The
constancy or inconstancy of employment cannot affect the ordinary
profits of stock in any particular trade. Whether the stock
is or is not constantly employed depends. not upon the trade,
but the trader.
Fourthly,
the wages of labour vary accordingly to the small or great
trust which must be reposed in the workmen.
The
wages of goldsmiths and jewellers are everywhere superior
to those of many other workmen, not only of equal, but of
much superior ingenuity, on account of the precious materials
with which they are intrusted.
We
trust our health to the physician: our fortune and sometimes
our life and reputation to the lawyer and attorney. Such confidence
could not safely be reposed in people of a very mean or low
condition. Their reward must be such, therefore, as may give
them that rank in the society which so important a trust requires.
The long time and the great expense which must be laid out
in their education, when combined with this circumstance,
necessarily enhance still further the price of their labour.
When
a person employs only his own stock in trade, there is no
trust; and the credit which he may get from other people depends,
not upon the nature of his trade, but upon their opinion of
his fortune, probity, and prudence. The different rates of
profit, therefore, in the different branches of trade, cannot
arise from the different degrees of trust reposed in the traders.
Fifthly,
the wages of labour in different. employments vary according
to the probability or improbability of success in them.
The
probability that any particular person shall ever be qualified
for the employment to which he is educated is very different
in different occupations. In the greater part of mechanic
trades, success is almost certain; but very uncertain in the
liberal professions. Put your son apprentice to a shoemaker,
there is little doubt of his learning to make a pair of shoes;
but send him to study the law, it is at least twenty to one
if ever he makes such proficiency as will enable him to live
by the business. In a perfectly fair lottery, those who draw
the prizes ought to gain all that is lost by those who draw
the blanks. In a profession where twenty fail for one that
succeeds, that one ought to gain all that should have been
gained by the unsuccessful twenty. The counsellor-at-law who,
perhaps, at near forty years of age, begins to make something
by his profession, ought to receive the retribution, not only
of his own so tedious and expensive education, but that of
more than twenty others who are never likely to make anything
by it. How extravagant soever the fees of counsellors-at-law
may sometimes appear, their real retribution is never equal
to this. Compute in any particular place what is likely to
be annually gained, and what is likely to be annually spent,
by all the different workmen in any common trade, such as
that of shoemakers or weavers, and you will find that the
former sum will generally exceed the latter. But make the
same computation with regard to all the counsellors and students
of law, in all the different inns of court, and you will find
that their annual gains bear but a very small proportion to
their annual expense, even though you rate the former as high,
and the latter as low, as can well be done. The lottery of
the law, therefore, is very far from being a perfectly fair
lottery; and that, as well as many other liberal and honourable
professions, are, in point of pecuniary gain, evidently under-recompensed.
Those
professions keep their level, however, with other occupations,
and, notwithstanding these discouragements, all the most generous
and liberal spirits are eager to crowd into them. Two different
causes contribute to recommend them. First, the desire of
the reputation which attends upon superior excellence in any
of them; and, secondly, the natural confidence which every
man has more or less, not only in his own abilities, but in
his own good fortune.
To
excel in any profession, in which but few arrive at mediocrity,
is the most decisive mark of what is called genius or superior
talents. The public admiration which attends upon such distinguished
abilities makes always a part of their reward; a greater or
smaller in proportion as it is higher or lower in degree.
It makes a considerable part of that reward in the profession
of physic; a still greater perhaps in that of law; in poetry
and philosophy it makes almost the whole.
There
are some very agreeable and beautiful talents of which the
possession commands a certain sort of admiration; but of which
the exercise for the sake of gain is considered, whether from
reason or prejudice, as a sort of public prostitution. The
pecuniary recompense, therefore, of those who exercise them
in this manner must be sufficient, not only to pay for the
time, labour, and expense of acquiring the talents, but for
the discredit which attends the employment of them as the
means of subsistence. The exorbitant rewards of players, opera-singers,
opera-dancers, etc., are founded upon those two principles;
the rarity and beauty of the talents, and the discredit of
employing them in this manner. It seems absurd at first sight
that we should despise their persons and yet reward their
talents with the most profuse liberality. While we do the
one, however, we must of necessity do the other. Should the
public opinion or prejudice ever alter with regard to such
occupations, their pecuniary recompense would quickly diminish.
More people would apply to them, and the competition would
quickly reduce the price of their labour. Such talents, though
far from being common, are by no means so rare as is imagined.
Many people possess them in great perfection, who disdain
to make this use of them; and many more are capable of acquiring
them, if anything could be made honourably by them.
The
overweening conceit which the greater part of men have of
their own abilities is an ancient evil remarked by the philosophers
and moralists of all ages. Their absurd presumption in their
own good fortune has been less taken notice of. It is, however,
if possible, still more universal. There is no man living
who, when in tolerable health and spirits, has not some share
of it. The chance of gain is by every man more or less overvalued,
and the chance of loss is by most men undervalued, and by
scarce any man, who is in tolerable health and spirits, valued
more than it is worth.
That
the chance of gain is naturally overvalued, we may learn from
the universal success of lotteries. The world neither ever
saw, nor ever will see, a perfectly fair lottery; or one in
which the whole gain compensated the whole loss; because the
undertaker could make nothing by it. In the state lotteries
the tickets are really not worth the price which is paid by
the original subscribers, and yet commonly sell in the market
for twenty, thirty, and sometimes forty per cent advance.
The vain hope of gaining some of the great prizes is the sole
cause of this demand. The soberest people scarce look upon
it as a folly to pay a small sum for the chance of gaining
ten or twenty thousand pounds; though they know that even
that small sum is perhaps twenty or thirty per cent more than
the chance is worth. In a lottery in which no prize exceeded
twenty pounds, though in other respects it approached much
nearer to a perfectly fair one than the common state lotteries,
there would not be the same demand for tickets. In order to
have a better chance for some of the great prizes, some people
purchase several tickets, and others, small share in a still
greater number. There is not, however, a more certain proposition
in mathematics than that the more tickets you adventure upon,
the more likely you are to be a loser. Adventure upon all
the tickets in the lottery, and you lose for certain; and
the greater the number of your tickets the nearer you approach
to this certainty.
That
the chance of loss is frequently undervalued, and scarce ever
valued more than it is worth, we may learn from a very moderate
profit of insurers. In order to make insurance, either from
fire or sea-risk, a trade at all, the common premium must
be sufficient to compensate the common losses, to pay the
expense of management, and to afford such a profit as might
have been drawn from an equal capital employed in any common
trade. The person who pays no more than this evidently pays
no more than the real value of the risk, or the lowest price
at which he can reasonably expect to insure it. But though
many people have made a little money by insurance, very few
have made a great fortune; and from this consideration alone,
it seems evident enough that the ordinary balance of profit
and loss is not more advantageous in this than in other common
trades by which so many people make fortunes. Moderate, however,
as the premium of insurance commonly is, many people despise
the risk too much to care to pay it. Taking the whole kingdom
at an average, nineteen houses in twenty, or rather perhaps
ninety-nine in a hundred, are not insured from fire. Sea risk
is more alarming to the greater part of people, and the proportion
of ships insured to those not insured is much greater. Many
fail, however, at all seasons, and even in time of war, without
any insurance. This may sometimes perhaps be done without
any imprudence. When a great company, or even a great merchant,
has twenty or thirty ships at sea, they may, as it were, insure
one another. The premium saved upon them all may more than
compensate such losses as they are likely to meet with in
the common course of chances. The neglect of insurance upon
shipping, however, in the same manner as upon houses, is,
in most cases, the effect of no such nice calculation, but
of mere thoughtless rashness and presumptuous contempt of
the risk.
The
contempt of risk and the presumptuous hope of success are
in no period of life more active than at the age at which
young people choose their professions. How little the fear
of misfortune is then capable of balancing the hope of good
luck appears still more evidently in the readiness of the
common People to enlist as soldiers, or to go to sea, than
in the eagerness of those of better fashion to enter into
what are called the liberal professions.
What
a common soldier may lose is obvious enough. Without regarding
the danger, however, young volunteers never enlist so readily
as at the beginning of a new war; and though they have scarce
any chance of preferment, they figure to themselves, in their
youthful fancies, a thousand occasions of acquiring honour
and distinction which never occur. These romantic hopes make
the whole price of their blood. Their pay is less than that
of common labourers, and in actual service their fatigues
are much greater.
The
lottery of the sea is not altogether so disadvantageous as
that of the army. The son of a creditable labourer or artificer
may frequently go to sea with his father's consent; but if
he enlists as a soldier, it is always without it. Other people
see some chance of his making something by the one trade:
nobody but himself sees any of his making anything by the
other. The great admiral is less the object of public admiration
than the great general, and the highest success in the sea
service promises a less brilliant fortune and reputation than
equal success in the land. The same difference runs through
all the inferior degrees of preferment in both. By the rules
of precedency a captain in the navy ranks with a colonel in
the army; but he does not rank with him in the common estimation.
As the great prizes in the lottery are less, the smaller ones
must be more numerous. Common sailors, therefore, more frequently
get some fortune and preferment than common soldiers; and
the hope of those prizes is what principally recommends the
trade. Though their skill and dexterity are much superior
to that of almost any artificers, and though their whole life
is one continual scene of hardship and danger, yet for all
this dexterity and skill, for all those hardships and dangers,
while they remain in the condition of common sailors, they
receive scarce any other recompense but the pleasure of exercising
the one and of surmounting the other. Their wages are not
greater than those of common labourers at the port which regulates
the rate of seamen's wages. As they are continually going
from port to port, the monthly pay of those who sail from
all the different ports of Great Britain is more nearly upon
a level than that of any other workmen in those different
places; and the rate of the port to and from which the greatest
number sail, that is the port of London, regulates that of
all the rest. At London the wages of the greater part of the
different classes of workmen are about double those of the
same classes at Edinburgh. But the sailors who sail from the
port of London seldom earn above three or four shillings a
month more than those who sail from the port of Leith, and
the difference is frequently not so great. In time of peace,
and in the merchant service, the London price is from a guinea
to about seven-and-twenty shillings the calendar month. A
common labourer in London, at the rate of nine or ten shillings
a week, may earn in the calendar month from forty to five-and-forty
shillings. The sailor, indeed, over and above his pay, is
supplied with provisions. Their value, however, may not perhaps
always exceed the difference between his pay and that of the
common labourer; and though it sometimes should, the excess
will not be clear gain to the sailor, because he cannot share
it with his wife and family, whom he must maintain out of
his wages at home.
The
dangers and hairbreadth escapes of a life of adventures, instead
of disheartening young people, seem frequently to recommend
a trade to them. A tender mother, among the inferior ranks
of people, is of afraid to send her son to school at a seaport
town, lest the sight of the ships and the conversation and
adventures of the sailors should entice him to go to sea.
The distant prospect of hazards, from which we can hope to
extricate ourselves by courage and address, is not disagreeable
to us, and does not raise the wages of labour in any employment.
It is otherwise with those in which courage and address can
be of no avail. In trades which are known to be very unwholesome,
the wages of labour are always remarkably high. Unwholesomeness
is a species of disagreeableness, and its effects upon the
wages of labour are to be ranked under that general head.
In
all the different employments of stock, the ordinary rate
of profit varies more or less with the certainty or uncertainty
of the returns. These are in general less uncertain in the
inland than in the foreign trade, and in some branches of
foreign trade than in others; in the trade to North America,
for example, than in that to Jamaica. The ordinary rate of
profit always rises more or less with the risk. It does not,
however, seem to rise in proportion to it, or so as to compensate
it completely. Bankruptcies are most frequent in the most
hazardous trades. The most hazardous of all trades, that of
a smuggler, though when the adventure succeeds it is likewise
the most profitable, is the infallible road to bankruptcy.
The presumptuous hope of success seems to act here as upon
all other occasions, and to entice so many adventurers into
those hazardous trades, that their competition reduces their
profit below what is sufficient to compensate the risk. To
compensate it completely, the common returns ought, over and
above the ordinary profits of stock, not only to make up for
all occasional losses, but to afford a surplus profit to the
adventurers of the same nature with the profit of insurers.
But if the common returns were sufficient for all this, bankruptcies
would not be more frequent in these than in other trades.
Of
the five circumstances, therefore, which vary the wages of
labour, two only affect the profits of stock; the agreeableness
or disagreeableness of the business, and the risk or security
with which it is attended. In point of agreeableness, there
is little or no difference in the far greater part of the
different employments of stock; but a great deal in those
of labour; and the ordinary profit of stock, though it rises
with the risk, does not always seem to rise in proportion
to it. It should follow from all this, that, in the same society
or neighbourhood, the average and ordinary rates of profit
in the different employments of stock should be more nearly
upon a level than the pecuniary wages of the different sorts
of labour. They are so accordingly. The difference between
the earnings of a common labourer and those of a well employed
lawyer or physician, is evidently much greater than that between
the ordinary profits in any two different branches of trade.
The apparent difference, besides, in the profits of different
trades, is generally a deception arising from our not always
distinguishing what ought to be considered as wages, from
what ought to be considered as profit.
Apothecaries'
profit is become a bye-word, denoting something uncommonly
extravagant. This great apparent profit, however, is frequently
no more than the reasonable wages of labour. The skill of
an apothecary is a much nicer and more delicate matter than
that of any artificer whatever; and the trust which is reposed
in him is of much greater importance. He is the physician
of the poor in all cases, and of the rich when the distress
or danger is not very great. His reward, therefore, ought
to be suitable to his skill and his trust, and it arises generally
from the price at which he sells his drugs. But the whole
drugs which the best employed apothecary, in a large market
town, will sell in a year, may not perhaps cost him above
thirty or forty pounds. Though he should sell them, therefore,
for three or four hundred, or at a thousand per cent profit,
this may frequently be no more than the reasonable wages of
his labour charged, in the only way in which he can charge
them, upon the price of his drugs. The greater part of the
apparent profit is real wages disguised in the garb of profit.
In
a small seaport town, a little grocer will make forty or fifty
per cent upon a stock of a single hundred pounds, while a
considerable wholesale merchant in the same place will scarce
make eight or ten per cent upon a stock of ten thousand. The
trade of the grocer may be necessary for the conveniency of
the inhabitants, and the narrowness of the market may not
admit the employment of a larger capital in the business.
The man, however, must not only live by his trade, but live
by it suitably to the qualifications which it requires. Besides
possessing a little capital, he must be able to read, write,
and account, and must be a tolerable judge too of, perhaps,
fifty or sixty different sorts of goods, their prices, qualities,
and the markets where they are to be had cheapest. He must
have all the knowledge, in short, that is necessary for a
great merchant, which nothing hinders him from becoming but
the want of a sufficient capital. Thirty or forty pounds a
year cannot be considered as too great a recompense for the
labour of a person so Accomplished. Deduct this from the seemingly
great profits of his capital, and little more will remain,
perhaps, than the ordinary profits of stock. The greater part
of the apparent profit is, in this case too, real wages.
The
difference between the apparent profit of the retail and that
of the wholesale trade, is much less in the capital than in
small towns and country villages. Where ten thousand pounds
can be employed in the grocery trade, the wages of the grocer's
labour make but a very trifling addition to the real profits
of so great a stock. The apparent profits of the wealthy retailer,
therefore, are there more nearly upon a level with those of
the wholesale merchant. It is upon this account that goods
sold by retail are generally as cheap and frequently much
cheaper in the capital than in small towns and country villages.
Grocery goods, for example, are generally much cheaper; bread
and butcher's meat frequently as cheap. It costs no more to
bring grocery goods to the great town than to the country
village; but it costs a great deal more to bring corn and
cattle, as the greater part of them must be brought from a
much greater distance. The prime cost of grocery goods, therefore,
being the same in both places, they are cheapest where the
least profit is charged upon them. The prime cost of bread
and butcher's meat is greater in the great town than in the
country village; and though the profit is less, therefore,
they are not always cheaper there, but often equally cheap.
In such articles as bread and butcher's meat, the same cause,
which diminishes apparent profit, increases prime cost. The
extent of the market, by giving employment to greater stocks,
diminishes apparent profit; but by requiring supplies from
a greater distance, it increases prime cost. This diminution
of the one and increase of the other seem, in most cases,
nearly to counterbalance one another, which is probably the
reason that, though the prices of corn and cattle are commonly
very different in different parts of the kingdom, those of
bread and butcher's meat are generally very nearly the same
through the greater part of it.
Though
the profits of stock both in the wholesale and retail trade
are generally less in the capital than in small towns and
country villages, yet great fortunes are frequently acquired
from small beginnings in the former, and scarce ever in the
latter. In small towns and country villages, on account of
the narrowness of the market, trade cannot always be extended
as stock extends. In such places, therefore, though the rate
of a particular person's profits may be very high, the sum
or amount of them can never be very great, nor consequently
that of his annual accumulation. In great towns, on the contrary,
trade can be extended as stock increases, and the credit of
a frugal and thriving man increases much faster than his stock.
His trade is extended in proportion to the amount of both,
and the sum or amount of his profits is in proportion to the
extent of his trade, and his annual accumulation in proportion
to the amount of his profits. It seldom happens, however,
that great fortunes are made even in great towns by any one
regular, established, and well-known branch of business, but
in consequence of a long life of industry, frugality, and
attention. Sudden fortunes, indeed, are sometimes made in
such places by what is called the trade of speculation. The
speculative merchant exercises no one regular, established,
or well-known branch of business. He is a corn merchant this
year, and a wine merchant the next, and a sugar, tobacco,
or tea merchant the year after. He enters into every trade
when he foresees that it is likely to be more than commonly
profitable, and he quits it when he foresees that its profits
are likely to return to the level of other trades. His profits
and losses, therefore, can bear no regular proportion to those
of any one established and well-known branch of business.
A bold adventurer may sometimes acquire a considerable fortune
by two or three successful speculations; but is just as likely
to lose one by two or three unsuccessful ones. This trade
can be carried on nowhere but in great towns. It is only in
places of the most extensive commerce and correspondence that
the intelligence requisite for it can be had.
The
five circumstances above mentioned, though they occasion considerable
inequalities in the wages of labour and profits of stock,
occasion none in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages,
real or imaginary, of the different employments of either.
The nature of those circumstances is such that they make up
for a small pecuniary gain in some, and counterbalance a great
one in others.
In
order, however, that this equality may take place in the whole
of their advantages or disadvantages, three things are requisite
even where there is the most perfect freedom. First, the employments
must be well known and long established in the neighbourhood;
secondly, they must be in their ordinary, or what may be called
their natural state; and, thirdly, they must be the sole or
principal employments of those who occupy them.
First,
this equality can take place only in those employments which
are well known, and have been long established in the neighbourhood.
Where
all other circumstances are equal, wages are generally higher
in new than in old trades. When a projector attempts to establish
a new manufacture, he must at first entice his workmen from
other employments by higher wages than they can either earn
in their own trades, or than the nature of his work would
otherwise require, and a considerable time must pass away
before he can venture to reduce them to the common level.
Manufactures for which the demand arises altogether from fashion
and fancy are continually changing, and seldom last long enough
to be considered as old established manufactures. Those, on
the contrary, for which the demand arises chiefly from use
or necessity, are less liable to change, and the same form
or fabric may continue in demand for whole centuries together.
The wages of labour, therefore, are likely to be higher in
manufactures of the former than in those of the latter kind.
Birmingham deals chiefly in manufactures of the former kind;
Sheffield in those of the latter; and the wages of labour
in those two different places are said to be suitable to this
difference in the nature of their manufactures.
The
establishment of any new manufacture, of any new branch of
commerce, or of any new practice in agriculture, is always
a speculation, from which the projector promises himself extraordinary
profits. These profits sometimes are very great, and sometimes,
more frequently, perhaps, they are quite otherwise; but in
general they bear no regular proportion to those of other
old trades in the neighbourhood. If the project succeeds,
they are commonly at first very high. When the trade or practice
becomes thoroughly established and well known, the competition
reduces them to the level of other trades.
Secondly,
this equality in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages
of the different employments of labour and stock, can take
place only in the ordinary, or what may be called the natural
state of those employments.
The
demand for almost every different species of labour is sometimes
greater and sometimes less than usual. In the one case the
advantages of the employment rise above, in the other they
fall below the common level. The demand for country labour
is greater at hay-time and harvest than during the greater
part of the year; and wages rise with the demand. In time
of war, when forty or fifty thousand sailors are forced from
the merchant service into that of the king, the demand for
sailors to merchant ships necessarily rises with their scarcity,
and their wages upon such occasions commonly rise from a guinea
and seven-and-twenty shillings, to forty shillings and three
pounds a month. In a decaying manufacture, on the contrary,
many workmen, rather than quit their old trade, are contented
with smaller wages than would otherwise be suitable to the
nature of their employment.
The
profits of stock vary with the price of the commodities in
which it is employed. As the price of any commodity rises
above the ordinary or average rate, the profits of at least
some part of the stock that is employed in bringing it to
market, rise above their proper level, and as it falls they
sink below it. All commodities are more or less liable to
variations of price, but some are much more so than others.
In all commodities which are produced by human industry, the
quantity of industry annually employed is necessarily regulated
by the annual demand, in such a manner that the average annual
produce may, as nearly as possible, be equal to the average
annual consumption. In some employments, it has already been
observed, the same quantity of industry will always produce
the same, or very nearly the same quantity of commodities.
In the linen or woollen manufactures, for example, the same
number of hands will annually work up very nearly the same
quantity of linen and woollen cloth. The variations in the
market price of such commodities, therefore, can arise only
from some accidental variation in the demand. A public mourning
raises the price of black cloth. But as the demand for most
sorts of plain linen and woollen cloth is pretty uniform,
so is likewise the price. But there are other employments
in which the same quantity of industry will not always produce
the same quantity of commodities. The same quantity of industry,
for example, will, in different years, produce very different
quantities of corn, wine, hops, sugar, tobacco, etc. The price
of such commodities, therefore, varies not only with the variations
of demand, but with the much greater and more frequent variations
of quantity, and is consequently extremely fluctuating. But
the profit of some of the dealers must necessarily fluctuate
with the price of the commodities. The operations of the speculative
merchant are principally employed about such commodities.
He endeavours to buy them up when he foresees that their price
is likely to rise, and to sell them when it is likely to fall.
Thirdly,
this equality in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages
of the different employments of labour and stock can take
only in such as are the sole or principal employments of those
who occupy them.
When
a person derives his subsistence from one employment, which
does not occupy the greater part of his time, in the intervals
of his leisure he is often willing to work as another for
less wages than would otherwise suit the nature of the employment.
There
still subsists in many parts of Scotland a set of people called
Cotters or Cottagers, though they were more frequent some
years ago than they are now. They are a sort of outservants
of the landlords and farmers. The usual reward which they
receive from their masters is a house, a small garden for
pot-herbs, as much grass as will feed a cow, and, perhaps,
an acre or two of bad arable land. When their master has occasion
for their labour, he gives them, besides, two pecks of oatmeal
a week, worth about sixteenpence sterling. During a great
part of the year he has little or no occasion for their labour,
and the cultivation of their own little possession is not
sufficient to occupy the time which is left at their own disposal.
When such occupiers were more numerous than they are at present,
they are said to have been willing to give their spare time
for a very small recompense to anybody, and to have wrought
for less wages than other labourers. In ancient times they
seem to have been common all over Europe. In countries ill
cultivated and worse inhabited, the greater part of landlords
and farmers could not otherwise provide themselves with the
extraordinary number of hands which country labour requires
at certain season. The daily or weekly recompense which such
labourers occasionally received from their masters was evidently
not the whole price of their labour. Their small tenement
made a considerable part of it. This daily or weekly recompense,
however, seems to have been considered as the whole of it,
by many writers who have collected the prices of labour and
provisions in ancient times, and who have taken pleasures
in representing both as wonderfully low.
The
produce of such labour comes frequently cheaper to market
than would otherwise suitable to its nature. Stockings in
many parts of Scotland are knit much cheaper than they can
anywhere be wrought upon the loom. They are the work of servants
and labourers, who derive the principal part of their subsistence
from some other employment. More than a thousand pair of Shetland
stockings are annually imported into Leith, of which the price
is from fivepence to sevenpence a pair. At Lerwick, the small
capital of the Shetland Islands, tenpence a day, I have been
assured, is a common price of common labour. In the same islands
they knit worsted stockings to the value of a guinea a pair
and upwards.
The
spinning of linen yarn is carried on in Scotland nearly in
the same way as the knitting of stockings by servants, who
are chiefly hired for other purposes. They earn but a very
scanty subsistence, who endeavour to get their whole livelihood
by either of those trades. In most parts of Scotland she is
a good spinner who can earn twentypence a week.
In
opulent countries the market is generally so extensive that
any one trade is sufficient to employ the whole labour and
stock of those who occupy it. Instances of people's living
by one employment, and at the same time deriving some little
advantage from another, occur chiefly in poor countries. The
following instance, however, of something of the same kind
is to be found in the capital of a very rich one. There is
no city in Europe, I believe, in which house-rent is dearer
than in London, and yet I know no capital in which a furnished
apartment can be hired as cheap. Lodging is not only much
cheaper in London than in Paris; it is much cheaper than in
Edinburgh of the same degree of goodness; and what may seem
extraordinary, the dearness of house-rent is the cause of
the cheapness of lodging. The dearness of house-rent in London
arises not only from those causes which render it dear in
all great capitals, the dearness of labour, the dearness of
all the materials of building, which must generally be brought
from a great distance, and above all the dearness of ground-rent,
every landlord acting the part the part of a monopolist, and
frequently exacting a higher rent for a single acre of bad
land in a town than can be had for a hundred of the best in
the country; but it arises in part from the peculiar manners
and customs of the people, which oblige every master of a
family to hire a whole house from top to bottom. A dwelling-house
in England means everything that is contained under the same
roof. In France, Scotland, and many other parts of Europe,
it frequently means no more than a single story. A tradesman
in London is obliged to hire a whole house in that part of
the town where his customers live. His shop is upon the ground-floor,
and he and his family sleep in the garret; and he endeavours
to pay a part of his house-rent by letting the two middle
stories to lodgers. He expects to maintain his family by his
trade, and not by his lodgers. Whereas, at Paris and Edinburgh,
the people who let lodgings have commonly no other means of
subsistence and the price of the lodging must pay, not only
the rent of the house, but the whole expense of the family.
Part
2: Inequalities by the Policy of Europe
Such
are the inequalities in the whole of advantages and disadvantages
of the different employments of labour and stock, which the
defect of any of the three requisites above mentioned must
occasion, even where there is the most perfect liberty. But
the policy of Europe, by not leaving things at perfect liberty,
occasions other inequalities of much greater importance.
It
does this chiefly in the three following ways. First, by restraining
the competition in some employments to a smaller number than
would otherwise be disposed to enter into them; secondly,
by increasing it in others beyond what it naturally would
be; and, thirdly, by obstructing the free circulation of labour
and stock, both from employment to employment and from place
to place.
First,
the policy of Europe occasions a very important inequality
in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages of the different
employments of labour and stock, by restraining the competition
in some employments to a smaller number than might otherwise
be disposed to enter into them.
The
exclusive privileges of corporations are the principal means
it makes use of for this purpose.
The
exclusive privilege of an incorporated trade necessarily restrains
the competition, in the town where it is established, to those
who are free of the trade. To have served an apprenticeship
in the town, under a master properly qualified, is commonly
the necessary requisite for obtaining this freedom. The bye
laws of the corporation regulate sometimes the number of apprentices
which any master is allowed to have, and almost always the
number of years which each apprentice is obliged to serve.
The intention of both regulations is to restrain the competition
to a much smaller number than might otherwise be disposed
to enter into the trade. The limitation of the number of apprentices
restrains it directly. A long term of apprenticeship restrains
it more indirectly, but as effectually, by increasing the
expense of education.
In
Sheffield no master cutler can have more than one apprentice
at a time, by a bye law of the corporation. In Norfolk and
Norwich no master weaver can have more than two apprentices,
under pain of forfeiting five pounds a month to the king.
No master hatter can have more than two apprentices anywhere
in England, or in the English plantations, under pain of forfeiting
five pounds a month, half to the king and half to him who
shall sue in any court of record. Both these regulations,
though they have been confirmed by a public law of the kingdom,
are evidently dictated by the same corporation spirit which
enacted the bye-law of Sheffield. The silk weavers in London
had scarce been incorporated a year when they enacted a bye-law
restraining any master from having more than two apprentices
at a time. It required a particular Act of Parliament to rescind
this bye law.
Seven
years seem anciently to have been, all over Europe, the usual
term established for the duration of apprenticeships in the
greater part of incorporated trades. All such incorporations
were anciently called universities, which indeed is the proper
Latin name for any incorporation whatever. The university
of smiths, the university of tailors, etc., are expressions
which we commonly meet with in the old charters of ancient
towns. When those particular incorporations which are now
peculiarly called universities were first established, the
term of years which it was necessary to study, in order to
obtain the degree of master of arts, appears evidently to
have been copied from the terms of apprenticeship in common
trades, of which the incorporations were much more ancient.
As to have wrought seven years under a master properly qualified
was necessary in order to entitle any person to become a master,
and to have himself apprenticed in a common trade; so to have
studied seven years under a master properly qualified was
necessary to entitle him to become a master, teacher, or doctor
(words anciently synonymous) in the liberal arts, and to have
scholars or apprentices (words likewise originally synonymous)
to study under him.
By
the 5th of Elizabeth, commonly called the Statute of Apprenticeship,
it was enacted, that no person should for the future exercise
any trade, craft, or mystery at that time exercised in England,
unless he had previously served to it an apprenticeship of
seven years at least; and what before had been the bye law
of many particular corporations became in England the general
and public law of all trades carried on in market towns. For
though the words of the statute are very general, and seem
plainly to include the whole kingdom, by interpretation its
operation has been limited to market towns, it having been
held that in country villages a person may exercise several
different trades, though he has not served a seven years'
apprenticeship to each, they being necessary for the conveniency
of the inhabitants, and the number of people frequently not
being sufficient to supply each with a particular set of hands.
By
a strict interpretation of the words, too, the operation of
this statute has been limited to those trades which were established
in England before the 5th of Elizabeth, and has never been
extended to such as have been introduced since that time.
This limitation has given occasion to several distinctions
which, considered as rules of police, appear as foolish as
can well be imagined. It has been adjudged, for example, that
a coachmaker can neither himself make nor employ journeymen
to make his coach-wheels, but must buy them of a master wheel-wright;
this latter trade having been exercised in England before
the 5th of Elizabeth. But a wheelwright, though he has never
served an apprenticeship to a coachmaker, may either himself
make or employ journeyman to make coaches; the trade of a
coachmaker not being within the statute, because not exercised
in England at the time when it was made. The manufactures
of Manchester, Birmingham, and Wolverhampton, are many of
them, upon this account, not within the statute, not having
been exercised in England before the 5th of Elizabeth.
In
France, the duration of apprenticeships is different in different
towns and in different trades. In Paris, five years is the
term required in a great number; but before any person can
be qualified to exercise the trade as a master, he must, in
many of them, serve five years more as a journeyman. During
this latter term he is called the companion of his master,
and the term itself is called his companionship.
In
Scotland there is no general law which regulates universally
the duration of apprenticeships. The term is different in
different corporations. Where it is long, a part of it may
generally be redeemed by paying a small fine. In most towns,
too, a very small fine is sufficient to purchase the freedom
of any corporation. The weavers of linen and hempen cloth,
the principal manufactures of the country, as well as all
other artificers subservient to them, wheel-makers, reel-makers,
etc., may exercise their trades in any town corporate without
paying any fine. In all towns corporate all persons are free
to sell butcher's meat upon any lawful day of the week. Three
years in Scotland is a common term of apprenticeship, even
in some very nice trades; and in general I know of no country
in Europe in which corporation laws are so little oppressive.
The
property which every man has in his own labour, as it is the
original foundation of all other property, so it is the most
sacred and inviolable. The patrimony of a poor man lies in
the strength and dexterity of his hands; and to hinder him
from employing this strength and dexterity of his hands; and
to hinder him from employing this strength and dexterity in
what manner he thinks proper without injury to his neighbour
is a plain violation of this most sacred property. It is a
manifest encroachment upon the just liberty both of the workman
and of those who might be disposed to employ him. As it hinders
the one from working at what he thinks proper, so it hinders
the others from employing whom they think proper. To judge
whether he is fit to be employed may surely be trusted to
the discretion of the employers whose interest it so much
concerns. The affected anxiety of the law-giver lest they
should employ an improper person is evidently as impertinent
as it is oppressive.
The
institution of long apprenticeships can give no security that
insufficient workmanship shall not frequently be exposed to
public sale. When this is done it is generally the effect
of fraud, and not of inability; and the longest apprenticeship
can give no security against fraud. Quite different regulations
are necessary to prevent this abuse. The sterling mark upon
plate, and the stamps upon linen and woollen cloth, give the
purchaser much greater security than any statute of apprenticeship.
He generally looks at these, but never thinks it worth while
to inquire whether the workman had served a seven years' apprenticeship.
The
institution of long apprenticeships has no tendency to form
a young people to industry. A journeyman who works by the
piece is likely to be industrious, because he derives a benefit
from every exertion of his industry. An apprentice is likely
to be idle, and almost always is so, because he has no immediate
interest to be otherwise. In the inferior employments, the
sweets of labour consist altogether in the recompense of labour.
They who are soonest in a condition to enjoy the sweets of
it are likely soonest to conceive a relish for it, and to
acquire the early habit of industry. A young man naturally
conceives an aversion to labour when for a long time he receives
no benefit from it. The boys who are put out apprentices from
public charities are generally bound for more than the usual
number of years, and they generally turn out very idle and
worthless.
Apprenticeships
were altogether unknown to the ancients. The reciprocal duties
of master and apprentice make a considerable article in every
modern code. The Roman law is perfectly silent with regard
to them. I know no Greek or Latin word (I might venture, I
believe, to assert that there is none) which expresses the
idea we now annex to the word Apprentice, a servant bound
to work at a particular trade for the benefit of a master,
during a term of years, upon condition that the master shall
teach him that trade.
Long
apprenticeships are altogether unnecessary. The arts, which
are much superior to common trades, such as those of making
clocks and watches, contain no such mystery as to require
a long course of instruction. The first invention of such
beautiful machines, indeed, and even that of some of the instruments
employed in making them, must, no doubt, have been the work
of deep thought and long time, and may justly be considered
as among the happiest efforts of human ingenuity. But when
both have been fairly invented and are well understood, to
explain to any young man, in the completest manner, how to
apply the instruments and how to construct the machines, cannot
well require more than the lessons of a few weeks: perhaps
those of a few days might be sufficient. In the common mechanic
trades, those of a few days might certainly be sufficient.
The dexterity of hand, indeed, even in common trades, cannot
be acquired without much practice and experience. But a young
man would practice with much more diligence and attention,
if from the beginning he wrought as a journeyman, being paid
in proportion to the little work which he could execute, and
paying in his turn for the materials which he might sometimes
spoil through awkwardness and inexperience. His education
would generally in this way be more effectual, and always
less tedious and expensive. The master, indeed, would be a
loser. He would lose all the wages of the apprentice, which
he now saves, for seven years together. In the end, perhaps,
the apprentice himself would be a loser. In a trade so easily
learnt he would have more competitors, and his wages, when
he came to be a complete workman, would be much less than
at present. The same increase of competition would reduce
the profits of the masters as well as the wages of the workmen.
The trades, the crafts, the mysteries, would all be losers.
But the public would be a gainer, the work of all artificers
coming in this way much cheaper to market.
It
is to prevent this reduction of price, and consequently of
wages and profit, by restraining that free competition which
would most certainly occasion it, that all corporations, and
the greater part of corporation laws, have been established.
In order to erect a corporation, no other authority in ancient
times was requisite in many parts of Europe, but that of the
town corporate in which it was established. In England, indeed,
a charter from the king was likewise necessary. But this prerogative
of the crown seems to have been reserved rather for extorting
money from the subject than for the defence of the common
liberty against such oppressive monopolies. Upon paying a
fine to the king, the charter seems generally to have been
readily granted; and when any particular class of artificers
or traders thought proper to act as a corporation without
a charter, such adulterine guilds, as they were called, were
not always disfranchised upon that account, but obliged to
fine annually to the king for permission to exercise their
usurped privileges. The immediate inspection of all corporations,
and of the bye-laws which they might think proper to enact
for their own government, belonged to the town corporate in
which they were established; and whatever discipline was exercised
over them proceeded commonly, not from the king, but from
the greater incorporation of which those subordinate ones
were only parts or members.
The
government of towns corporate was altogether in the hands
of traders and artificers, and it was the manifest interest
of every particular class of them to prevent the market from
being overstocked, as they commonly express it, with their
own particular species of industry, which is in reality to
keep it always understocked. Each class was eager to establish
regulations proper for this purpose, and, provided it was
allowed to do so, was willing to consent that every other
class should do the same. In consequence of such regulations,
indeed, each class was obliged to buy the goods they had occasion
for from every other within the town, somewhat dearer than
they otherwise might have done. But in recompense, they were
enabled to sell their own just as much dearer; so that so
far it was as broad as long, as they say; and in the dealings
of the different classes within the town with one another,
none of them were losers by these regulations. But in their
dealings with the country they were all great gainers; and
in these latter dealings consists the whole trade which supports
and enriches every town.
Every
town draws its whole subsistence, and all the materials of
its industry, from the country. It pays for these chiefly
in two ways: first, by sending back to the country a part
of those materials wrought up and manufactured; in which case
their price is augmented by the wages of the workmen, and
the profits of their masters or immediate employers; secondly,
by sending to it a part both of the rude and manufactured
produce, either of other countries, or of distant parts of
the same country, imported into the town; in which case, too,
the original price of those goods is augmented by the wages
of the carriers or sailors, and by the profits of the merchants
who employ them. In what is gained upon the first of those
two branches of commerce consists the advantage which the
town makes by its manufactures; in what is gained upon the
second, the advantage of its inland and foreign trade. The
wages of the workmen, and the profits of their different employers,
make up the whole of what is gained upon both. Whatever regulations,
therefore, tend to increase those wages and profits beyond
what they otherwise would be, tend to enable the town to purchase,
with a smaller quantity of its labour, the produce of a greater
quantity of the labour of the country. They give the traders
and artificers in the town an advantage over the landlords,
farmers, and labourers in the country, and break down that
natural equality which would otherwise take place in the commerce
which is carried on between them. The whole annual produce
of the labour of the society is annually divided between those
two different sets of people. By means of those regulations
a greater share of it is given to the inhabitants of the town
than would otherwise fall to them; and a less to those of
the country.
The
price which the town really pays for the provisions and materials
annually imported into it is the quantity of manufactures
and other goods annually exported from it. The dearer the
latter are sold, the cheaper the former are bought. The industry
of the town becomes more, and that of the country less advantageous.
That
the industry which is carried on in towns is, everywhere in
Europe, more advantageous than that which is carried on in
the country, without entering into any very nice computations,
we may satisfy ourselves by one very simple and obvious observation.
In every country of Europe we find, at least, a hundred people
who have acquired great fortunes from small beginnings by
trade and manufactures, the industry which properly belongs
to towns, for one who has done so by that which properly belongs
to the country, the raising of rude produce by the improvement
and cultivation of land. Industry, therefore, must be better
rewarded, the wages of labour and the profits of stock must
evidently be greater in the one situation than in the other.
But stock and labour naturally seek the most advantageous
employment. They naturally, therefore, resort as much as they
can to the town, and desert the country.
The
inhabitants of a town, being collected into one place, can
easily combine together. The most insignificant trades carried
on in towns have accordingly, in some place or other, been
incorporated, and even where they have never been incorporated,
yet the corporation spirit, the jealousy of strangers, the
aversion to take apprentices, or to communicate the secret
of their trade, generally prevail in them, and often teach
them, by voluntary associations and agreements, to prevent
that free competition which they cannot prohibit by bye-laws.
The trades which employ but a small number of hands run most
easily into such combinations. Half a dozen wool-combers,
perhaps, are necessary to keep a thousand spinners and weavers
at work. By combining not to take apprentices they can not
only engross the employment, but reduce the whole manufacture
into a sort of slavery to themselves, and raise the price
of their labour much above what is due to the nature of their
work.
The
inhabitants of the country, dispersed in distant places, cannot
easily combine together. They have not only never been incorporated,
but the corporation spirit never has prevailed among them.
No apprenticeship has ever been thought necessary to qualify
for husbandry, the great trade of the country. After what
are called the fine arts, and the liberal professions, however,
there is perhaps no trade which requires so great a variety
of knowledge and experience. The innumerable volumes which
have been written upon it in all languages may satisfy us
that, among the wisest and most learned nations, it has never
been regarded as a matter very easily understood. And from
all those volumes we shall in vain attempt to collect that
knowledge of its various and complicated operations, which
is commonly possessed even by the common farmer; how contemptuously
soever the very contemptible authors of some of them may sometimes
affect to speak of him. There is scarce any common mechanic
trade, on the contrary, of which all the operations may not
be as completely and distinctly explained in a pamphlet of
a very few pages, as it is possible for words illustrated
by figures to explain them. In the history of the arts, now
publishing by the French Academy of Sciences, several of them
are actually explained in this manner. The direction of operations,
besides, which must be varied with every change of the weather,
as well as with many other accidents, requires much more judgment
and discretion than that of those which are always the same
or very nearly the same.
Not
only the art of the farmer, the general direction of the operations
of husbandry, but many inferior branches of country labour
require much more skin and experience than the greater part
of mechanic trades. The man who works upon brass and iron,
works with instruments and upon materials of which the temper
is always the same, or very nearly the same. But the man who
ploughs the ground with a team of horses or oxen, works with
instruments of which the health, strength, and temper, are
very different upon different occasions. The condition of
the materials which he works upon, too, is as variable as
that of the instruments which he works with, and both require
to be managed with much judgment and discretion. The common
ploughman, though generally regarded as the pattern of stupidity
and ignorance, is seldom defective in this judgment and discretion.
He is less accustomed, indeed, to social intercourse than
the mechanic who lives in a town. His voice and language are
more uncouth and more difficult to be understood by those
who are not used to them. His understanding, however, being
accustomed to consider a greater variety of objects, is generally
much superior to that of the other, whose whole attention
from morning till night is commonly occupied in performing
one or two very simple operations. How much the lower ranks
of people in the country are really superior to those of the
town is well known to every man whom either business or curiosity
has led to converse much with both. In China and Indostan
accordingly both the rank and the wages of country labourers
are said to be superior to those of the greater part of artificers
and manufacturers. They would probably be so everywhere, if
corporation laws and the corporation spirit did not prevent
it.
The
superiority which the industry of the towns has everywhere
in Europe over that of the country is not altogether owing
to corporations and corporation laws. It is supported by many
other regulations. The high duties upon foreign manufactures
and upon all goods imported by alien merchants, all tend to
the same purpose. Corporation laws enable the inhabitants
of towns to raise their prices, without fearing to be undersold
by the free competition of their own countrymen. Those other
regulations secure them equally against that of foreigners.
The enhancement of price occasioned by both is everywhere
finally paid by the landlords, farmers, and labourers of the
country, who have seldom opposed the establishment of such
monopolies. They have commonly neither inclination nor fitness
to enter into combinations; and the clamour and sophistry
of merchants and manufacturers easily persuade them that the
private interest of a part, and of a subordinate part of the
society, is the general interest of the whole.
In
Great Britain the superiority of the industry of the towns
over that of the country seems to have been greater formerly
than in the present times. The wages of country labour approach
nearer to those of manufacturing labour, and the profits of
stock employed in agriculture to those of trading and manufacturing
stock, than they are said to have done in the last century,
or in the beginning of the present. This change may be regarded
as the necessary, though very late consequence of the extraordinary
encouragement given to the industry of the towns. The stock
accumulated in them comes in time to be so great that it can
no longer be employed with the ancient profit in that species
of industry which is peculiar to them. That industry has its
limits like every other; and the increase of stock, by increasing
the competition, necessarily reduces the profit. The lowering
of profit in the town forces out stock to the country, where,
by creating a new demand for country labour, it necessarily
raises its wages. It then spreads itself, if I may say so,
over the face of the land, and by being employed in agriculture
is in part restored to the country, at the expense of which,
in a great measure, it had originally been accumulated in
the town. That everywhere in Europe the greatest improvements
of the country have been owing to such overflowings of the
stock originally accumulated in the towns, I shall endeavour
to show hereafter; and at the same time to demonstrate that,
though some countries have by this course attained to a considerable
degree of opulence, it is in itself necessarily slow, uncertain,
liable to be disturbed and interrupted by innumerable accidents,
and in every respect contrary to the order of nature and of
reason. The interests, prejudices, laws and customs, which
have given occasion to it, I shall endeavour to explain as
fully and distinctly as I can in the third and fourth books
of this Inquiry.
People
of the same trade seldom meet together, even for merriment
and diversion, but the conversation ends in a conspiracy against
the public, or in some contrivance to raise prices. It is
impossible indeed to prevent such meetings, by any law which
either could be executed, or would be consistent with liberty
and justice. But though the law cannot hinder people of the
same trade from sometimes assembling together, it ought to
do nothing to facilitate such assemblies, much less to render
them necessary.
A
regulation which obliges all those of the same trade in a
particular town to enter their names and places of abode in
a public register, facilitates such assemblies. It connects
individuals who might never otherwise be known to one another,
and gives every man of the trade a direction where to find
every other man of it.
A
regulation which enables those of the same trade to tax themselves
in order to provide for their poor, their sick, their widows
and orphans, by giving them a common interest to manage, renders
such assemblies necessary.
An
incorporation not only renders them necessary, but makes the
act of the majority binding upon the whole. In a free trade
an effectual combination cannot be established but by the
unanimous consent of every single trader, and it cannot last
longer than every single trader continues of the same mind.
The majority of a corporation can enact a bye-law with proper
penalties, which will limit the competition more effectually
and more durably than any voluntary combination whatever.
The
pretence that corporations are necessary for the better government
of the trade is without any foundation. The real and effectual
discipline which is exercised over a workman is not that of
his corporation, but that of his customers. It is the fear
of losing their employment which restrains his frauds and
corrects his negligence. An exclusive corporation necessarily
weakens the force of this discipline. A particular set of
workmen must then be employed, let them behave well or ill.
It is upon this account that in many large incorporated towns
no tolerable workmen are to be found, even in some of the
most necessary trades. If you would have your work tolerably
executed, it must be done in the suburbs, where the workmen,
having no exclusive privilege, have nothing but their character
to depend upon, and you must then smuggle it into the town
as well as you can.
It
is in this manner that the policy of Europe, by restraining
the competition in some employments to a smaller number than
would otherwise be disposed to enter into them, occasions
a very important inequality in the whole of the advantages
and disadvantages of the different employments of labour and
stock.
Secondly,
the policy of Europe, by increasing the competition in some
employments beyond what it naturally would be, occasions another
inequality of an opposite kind in the whole of the advantages
and disadvantages of the different employments of labour and
stock.
It
has been considered as of so much importance that a proper
number of young people should be educated for certain professions,
that sometimes the public and sometimes the piety of private
founders have established many pensions, scholarships, exhibitions,
bursaries, etc., for this purpose, which draw many more people
into those trades than could otherwise pretend to follow them.
In all Christian countries, I believe, the education of the
greater part of churchmen is paid for in this manner. Very
few of them are educated altogether at their own expense.
The long, tedious, and expensive education, therefore, of
those who are, will not always procure them a suitable reward,
the church being crowded with people who, in order to get
employment, are willing to accept of a much smaller recompense
than what such an education would otherwise have entitled
them to; and in this manner the competition of the poor takes
away the reward of the rich. It would be indecent, no doubt,
to compare either a curate or a chaplain with a journeyman
in any common trade. The pay of a curate or chaplain, however,
may very properly be considered as of the same nature with
the wages of a journeyman. They are, all three, paid for their
work according to the contract which they may happen to make
with their respective superiors. Till after the middle of
the fourteenth century, five merks, containing about as much
silver as ten pounds of our present money, was in England
the usual pay of a curate or a stipendiary parish priest,
as we find it regulated by the decrees of several different
national councils. At the same period fourpence a day, containing
the same quantity of silver as a shilling of our present money,
was declared to be the pay of a master mason, and threepence
a day, equal to ninepence of our present money, that of a
journeyman mason. The wages of both these labourers, therefore,
supposing them to have been constantly employed, were much
superior to those of the curate. The wages of the master mason,
supposing him to have been without employment one third of
the year, would have fully equalled them. By the 12th of Queen
Anne, c. 12, it is declared, "That whereas for want of sufficient
maintenance and encouragement to curates, the cures have in
several places been meanly supplied, the bishop is, therefore,
empowered to appoint by writing under his band and seal a
sufficient certain stipend or allowance, not exceeding fifty
and not less than twenty pounds a year." Forty pounds a year
is reckoned at present very good pay for a curate, and notwithstanding
this Act of Parliament there are many curacies under twenty
pounds a year. There are journeymen shoemakers in London who
earn forty pounds a year, and there is scarce an industrious
workman of any kind in that metropolis who does not earn more
than twenty. This last sum indeed does not exceed what is
frequently earned by common labourers in many country parishes.
Whenever the law has attempted to regulate the wages of workmen,
it has always been rather to lower them than to raise them.
But the law has upon many occasions attempted to raise the
wages of curates, and for the dignity of the church, to oblige
the rectors of parishes to give them more than the wretched
maintenance which they themselves might be willing to accept
of. And in both cases the law seems to have been equally ineffectual,
and has never either been able to raise the wages of curates,
or to sink those of labourers to the degree that was intended;
because it has never been able to hinder either the one from
being willing to accept of less than the legal allowance,
on account of the indigence of their situation and the multitude
of their competitors; or the other from receiving more, on
account of the contrary competition of those who expected
to derive either profit or pleasure from employing them.
The
great benefices and other ecclesiastical dignities support
the honour of the church, notwithstanding the mean circumstance
of some of its inferior members. The respect paid to the profession,
too, makes some compensation even to them for the meanness
of their pecuniary recompense. In England, and in all Roman
Catholic countries, the lottery of the church is in reality
much more advantageous than is necessary. The example of the
churches of Scotland, of Geneva, and of several other Protestant
churches, may satisfy us that in so creditable a profession,
in which education is so easily procured, the hopes of much
more moderate benefices will draw a sufficient number of learned,
decent, and respectable men into holy orders.
In
professions in which there are no benefices, such as law and
physic, if an equal proportion of people were educated at
the public expense, the competition would soon be so great
as to sink very much their pecuniary reward. It might then
not be worth any man's while to educate his son to either
of those professions at his own expense. They would be entirely
abandoned to such as had been educated by those public charities,
whose numbers and necessities would oblige them in general
to content themselves with a very miserable recompense, to
the entire degradation of the now respectable professions
of law and physic.
That
unprosperous race of men commonly called men of letters are
pretty much in the situation which lawyers and physicians
probably would be in upon the foregoing supposition. In every
part of Europe the greater part of them have been educated
for the church, but have been hindered by different reasons
from entering into holy orders. They have generally, therefore,
been educated at the public expense, and their numbers are
everywhere so great as commonly to reduce the price of their
labour to a very paltry recompense.
Before
the invention of the art of printing, the only employment
by which a man of letters could make anything by his talents
was that of a public or private teacher, or by communicating
to other people the curious and useful knowledge which he
had acquired himself: and this is still surely a more honourable,
a more useful, and in general even a more profitable employment
than that other of writing for a bookseller, to which the
art of printing has given occasion. The time and study, the
genius, knowledge, and application requisite to qualify an
eminent teacher of the sciences, are at least equal to what
is necessary for the greatest practitioners in law and physic.
But the usual reward of the eminent teacher bears no proportion
to that of the lawyer or physician; because the trade of the
one is crowded with indigent people who have been brought
up to it at the public expense; whereas those of the other
two are encumbered with very few who have not been educated
at their own. The usual recompense, however, of public and
private teachers, small as it may appear, would undoubtedly
be less than it is, if the competition of those yet more indigent
men of letters who write for bread was not taken out of the
market. Before the invention of the art of printing, a scholar
and a beggar seem to have been terms very nearly synonymous.
The different governors of the universities before that time
appear to have often granted licences to their scholars to
beg.
In
ancient times, before any charities of this kind had been
established for the education of indigent people to the learned
professions, the rewards of eminent teachers appear to have
been much more considerable. Isocrates, in what is called
his discourse against the sophists, reproaches the teachers
of his own times with inconsistency. "They make the most magnificent
promises to their scholars," says he, "and undertake to teach
them to be wise, to be happy, and to be just, and in return
for so important a service they stipulate the paltry reward
of four or five minae. They who teach wisdom," continues he,
ought certainly to be wise themselves; but if any man were
to sell such a bargain for such a price, he would be convicted
of the most evident folly." He certainly does not mean here
to exaggerate the reward, and we may be assured that it was
not less than he represents it. Four minae were equal to thirteen
pounds six shillings and eightpence: five minae to sixteen
pounds thirteen shillings and fourpence. Something not less
than the largest of those two sums, therefore, must at that
time have been usually paid to the most eminent teachers at
Athens. Isocrates himself demanded ten minae, or thirty-three
pounds six shillings and eightpence, from each scholar. When
he taught at Athens, he is said to have had a hundred scholars.
I understand this to be the number whom he taught at one time,
or who attended what we could call one course of lectures,
a number which will not appear extraordinary from so great
a city to so famous a teacher, who taught, too, what was at
that time the most fashionable of all sciences, rhetoric.
He must have made, therefore, by each course of lectures,
a thousand minae, or L3333 6s. 8d. A thousand minae, accordingly,
is said by Plutarch in another place, to have been his Didactron,
or usual price of teaching. Many other eminent teachers in
those times appear to have acquired great fortunes. Gorgias
made a present to the temple of Delphi of his own statue in
solid gold. We must not, I presume, suppose that it was as
large as the life. His way of living, as well as that of Hippias
and Protagoras, two other eminent teachers of those times,
is represented by Plato as splendid even to ostentation. Plato
himself is said to have lived with a good deal of magnificence.
Aristotle, after having been tutor to Alexander, and most
munificently rewarded, as it is universally agreed, both by
him and his father Philip, thought it worth while, notwithstanding,
to return to Athens, in order to resume the teaching of his
school. Teachers of the sciences were probably in those times
less common than they came to be in an age or two afterwards,
when the competition had probably somewhat reduced both the
price of their labour and the admiration for their persons.
The most eminent of them, however, appear always to have enjoyed
a degree of consideration much superior to any of the like
profession in the present times. The Athenians sent Carneades
the Academic, and Diogenes the Stoic, upon a solemn embassy
to Rome; and though their city had then declined from its
former grandeur, it was still an independent and considerable
republic. Carneades, too, was a Babylonian by birth, and as
there never was a people more jealous of admitting foreigners
to public offices than the Athenians, their consideration
for him must have been very great.
This
inequality is upon the whole, perhaps, rather advantageous
than hurtful to the public. It may somewhat degrade the profession
of a public teacher; but the cheapness of literary education
is surely an advantage which greatly overbalances this trifling
inconveniency. The public, too, might derive still greater
benefit from it, if the constitution of those schools and
colleges, in which education is carried on, was more reasonable
than it is at present through the greater part of Europe.
Thirdly,
the policy of Europe, by obstructing the free circulation
of labour and stock both from employment to employment, and
from place to place, occasions in some cases a very incovenient
inequality in the whole of the advantages and disadvantages
of their different employments.
The
Statute of Apprenticeship obstructs the free circulation of
labour from one employment to another, even in the same place.
The exclusive privileges of corporations obstruct it from
one place to another, even in the same employment.
It
frequently happens that while high wages are given to the
workmen in one manufacture, those in another are obliged to
content themselves with bare subsistence. The one is in an
advancing state, and has, therefore, a continual demand for
new bands: the other is in a declining state, and the superabundance
of hands is continually increasing. Those two manufactures
may sometimes be in the same town, and sometimes in the same
neighbourhood, without being able to lend the least assistance
to one another. The Statute of Apprenticeship may oppose it
in the one case, and both that and an exclusive corporation
in the other. In many different manufactures, however, the
operations are so much alike, that the workmen could easily
change trades with one another, if those absurd laws did not
hinder them. The arts of weaving plain linen and plain silk,
for example, are almost entirely the same. That of weaving
plain woollen is somewhat different; but the difference is
so insignificant that either a linen or a silk weaver might
become a tolerable work in a very few days. If any of those
three capital manufactures, therefore, were decaying, the
workmen might find a resource in one of the other two which
was in a more prosperous condition; and their wages would
neither rise too high in the thriving, nor sink too low in
the decaying manufacture. The linen manufacture indeed is,
in England, by a particular statute, open to everybody; but
as it is not much cultivated through the greater part of the
country, it can afford no general resource to the workmen
of other decaying manufactures, who, wherever the Statute
of Apprenticeship takes place, have no other choice but either
to come upon the parish, or to work as common labourers, for
which, by their habits, they are much worse qualified than
for any sort of manufacture that bears any resemblance to
their own. They generally, therefore, choose to come upon
the parish.
Whatever
obstructs the free circulation of labour from one employment
to another obstructs that of stock likewise; the quantity
of stock which can be employed in any branch of business depending
very much upon that of the labour which can be employed in
it. Corporation laws, however, give less obstruction to the
free circulation of stock from one place to another than to
that of labour. It is everywhere much easier for a wealthy
merchant to obtain the privilege of trading in a town corporate,
than for a poor artificer to obtain that of working in it.
The
obstruction which corporation laws give to the free circulation
of labour is common, I believe, to every part of Europe. That
which is given to it by the Poor Laws is, so far as I know,
peculiar to England. It consists in the difficulty which a
poor man finds in obtaining a settlement, or even in being
allowed to exercise his industry in any parish but that to
which he belongs. It is the labour of artificers and manufacturers
only of which the free circulation is obstructed by corporation
laws. The difficulty of obtaining settlements obstructs even
that of common labour. It may be worth while to give some
account of the rise, progress, and present state of this disorder,
the greatest perhaps of any in the police of England.
When
by the destruction of monasteries the poor had been deprived
of the charity of those religious houses, after some other
ineffectual attempts for their relief, it was enacted by the
43rd of Elizabeth, c. 2, that every parish should be bound
to provide for its own poor; and that overseers of the poor
should be annually appointed, who, with the churchwardens,
should raise by a parish rate competent sums for this purpose.
By
this statute the necessity of providing for their own poor
was indispensably imposed upon every parish. Who were to be
considered as the poor of each parish became, therefore, a
question of some importance. This question, after some variation,
was at last determined by the 13th and 14th of Charles II
when it was enacted, that forty days' undisturbed residence
should gain any person a settlement in any parish; but that
within that time it should be lawful for two justices of the
peace, upon complaint made by the churchwardens or overseers
of the poor, to remove any new inhabitant to the parish where
he was last legally settled; unless he either rented a tenement
of ten pounds a year, or could give such security for the
discharge of the parish where he was then living, as those
justices should judge sufficient.
Some
frauds, it is said, were committed in consequence of this
statute; parish officers sometimes bribing their own poor
to go clandestinely to another parish, and by keeping themselves
concealed for forty days to gain a settlement there, to the
discharge of that to which they properly belonged. It was
enacted, therefore, by the 1st of James II that the forty
days' undisturbed residence of any person necessary to gain
a settlement should be accounted only from the time of his
delivering notice in writing, of the place of his abode and
the number of his family, to one of the churchwardens or overseers
of the parish where he came to dwell.
But
parish officers, it seems, were not always more honest with
regard to their own, than they had been with regard to other
parishes, and sometimes connived at such intrusions, receiving
the notice, and taking no proper steps in consequence of it.
As every person in a parish, therefore, was supposed to have
an interest to prevent as much as possible their being burdened
by such intruders, it was further enacted by the 3rd of William
III that the forty days' residence should be accounted only
from the publication of such notice in writing on Sunday in
the church, immediately after divine service.
"After
all," says Doctor Burn, "this kind of settlement, by continuing
forty days after publication of notice in writing, is very
seldom obtained; and the design of the acts is not so much
for gaining of settlements, as for the avoiding of them, by
persons coming into a parish clandestinely: for the giving
of notice is only putting a force upon the parish to remove.
But if a person's situation is such, that it is doubtful whether
he is actually removable or not, he shall by giving of notice
compel the parish either to allow him a settlement uncontested,
by suffering him to continue forty days; or, by removing him,
to try the right."
This
statute, therefore, rendered it almost impracticable for a
poor man to gain a new settlement in the old way, by forty
days' inhabitancy. But that it might not appear to preclude
altogether the common people of one parish from ever establishing
themselves with security in another, it appointed four other
ways by which a settlement might be gained without any notice
delivered or published. The first was, by being taxed to parish
rates and paying them; the second, by being elected into an
annual parish office, and serving in it a year; the third,
by serving an apprenticeship in the parish; the fourth, by
being hired into service there for a year, and continuing
in the same service during the whole of it.
Nobody
can gain a settlement by either of the two first ways, but
by the public deed of the whole parish, who are too well aware
of the consequences to adopt any new-comer who has nothing
but his labour to support him, either by taxing him to parish
rates, or by electing him into a parish office.
No
married man can well gain any settlement in either of the
two last ways. An apprentice is scarce ever married; and it
is expressly enacted that no married servant shall gain any
settlement by being hired for a year. The principal effect
of introducing settlement by service has been to put out in
a great measure the old fashion of hiring for a year, which
before had been so customary in England, that even at this
day, if no particular term is agreed upon, the law intends
that every servant is hired for a year. But masters are not
always willing to give their servants a settlement by hiring
them in this manner; and servants are not always willing to
be so hired, because, as every last settlement discharges
all the foregoing, they might thereby lose their original
settlement in the places of their nativity, the habitation
of their parents and relations.
No
independent workman, it is evident, whether labourer or artificer,
is likely to gain any new settlement either by apprenticeship
or by service. When such a person, therefore, carried his
industry to a new parish, he was liable to be removed, how
healthy and industrious soever, at the caprice of any churchwarden
or overseer, unless he either rented a tenement of ten pounds
a year, a thing impossible for one who has nothing but his
labour to live by; or could give such security for the discharge
of the parish as two justices of the peace should judge sufficient.
What security they shall require, indeed, is left altogether
to their discretion; but they cannot well require less than
thirty pounds, it having been enacted that the purchase even
of a freehold estate of less than thirty pounds' value shall
not gain any person a settlement, as not being sufficient
for the discharge of the parish. But this is a security which
scarce any man who lives by labour can give; and much greater
security is frequently demanded.
In
order to restore in some measure that free circulation of
labour which those different statutes had almost entirely
taken away, the invention of certificates was fallen upon.
By the 8th and 9th of William III it was enacted that if any
person should bring a certificate from the parish where he
was last legally settled, subscribed by the churchwardens
and overseers of the poor, and allowed by two justices of
the peace, that every other parish should be obliged to receive
him; that he should not be removable merely upon account of
his being likely to become chargeable, but only upon his becoming
actually chargeable, and that then the parish which granted
the certificate should be obliged to pay the expense both
of his maintenance and of his removal. And in order to give
the most perfect security to the parish where such certificated
man should come to reside, it was further enacted by the same
statute that he should gain no settlement there by any means
whatever, except either by renting a tenement of ten pounds
a year, or by serving upon his own account in an annual parish
office for one whole year; and consequently neither by notice,
nor by service, nor by apprenticeship, nor by paying parish
rates. By the 12th of Queen Anne, too, stat. 1, c. 18, it
was further enacted that neither the servants nor apprentices
of such certificated man should gain any settlement in the
parish where he resided under such certificate.
How
far this invention has restored that free circulation of labour
which the preceding statutes had almost entirely taken away,
we may learn from the following very judicious observation
of Doctor Burn. "It is obvious," says he, "that there are
divers good reasons for requiring certificates with persons
coming to settle in any place; namely, that persons residing
under them can gain no settlement, neither by apprenticeship,
nor by service, nor by giving notice, nor by paying parish
rates; that they can settle neither apprentices nor servants;
that if they become chargeable, it is certainly known whither
to remove them, and the parish shall be paid for the removal,
and for their maintenance in the meantime; and that if they
fall sick, and cannot be removed, the parish which gave the
certificate must maintain them: none of all which can be without
a certificate. Which reasons will hold proportionably for
parishes not granting certificates in ordinary cases; for
it is far more than an equal chance, but that they will have
the certificated persons again, and in a worse condition."
The moral of this observation seems to be that certificates
ought always to be required by the parish where any poor man
comes to reside, and that they ought very seldom to be granted
by that which he proposes to leave. "There is somewhat of
hardship in this matter of certificates," says the same very
intelligent author in his History of the Poor Laws, "by putting
it in the power of a parish officer to imprison a man as it
were for life; however inconvenient it may be for him to continue
at that place where he has had the misfortune to acquire what
is called a settlement, or whatever advantage he may propose
to himself by living elsewhere."
Though
a certificate carries along with it no testimonial of good
behaviour, and certifies nothing but that the person belongs
to the parish to which he really does belong, it is altogether
discretionary in the parish officers either to grant or to
refuse it. A mandamus was once moved for, says Doctor Burn,
to compel the churchwardens and overseers to sign a certificate;
but the court of King's Bench rejected the motion as a very
strange attempt.
The
very unequal price of labour which we frequently find in England
in places at no great distance from one another is probably
owing to the obstruction which the law of settlements gives
to a poor man who would carry his industry from one parish
to another without a certificate. A single man, indeed, who
is healthy and industrious, may sometimes reside by sufferance
without one; but a man with a wife and family who should attempt
to do so would in most parishes be sure of being removed,
and if the single man should afterwards marry, he would generally
be removed likewise. The scarcity of hands in one parish,
therefore, cannot always be relieved by their superabundance
in another, as it is constantly in Scotland, and, I believe,
in all other countries where there is no difficulty of settlement.
In such countries, though wages may sometimes rise a little
in the neighbourhood of a great town, or wherever else there
is an extraordinary demand for labour, and sink gradually
as the distance from such places increases, till they fall
back to the common rate of the country; yet we never meet
with those sudden and unaccountable differences in the wages
of neighbouring places which we sometimes find in England,
where it is often more difficult for a poor man to pass the
artificial boundary of a parish than an arm of the sea or
a ridge of high mountains, natural boundaries which sometimes
separate very distinctly different rates of wages in other
countries.
To
remove a man who has committed no misdemeanour from the parish
where he chooses to reside is an evident violation of natural
liberty and justice. The common people of England, however,
so jealous of their liberty, but like the common people of
most other countries never rightly understanding wherein it
consists, have now for more than a century together suffered
themselves to be exposed to this oppression without a remedy.
Though men of reflection, too, have sometimes complained of
the law of settlements as a public grievance; yet it has never
been the object of any general popular clamour, such as that
against general warrants, an abusive practice undoubtedly,
but such a one as was not likely to occasion any general oppression.
There is scarce a poor man in England of forty years of age,
I will venture to say, who has not in some part of his life
felt himself most cruelly oppressed by this illcontrived law
of settlements.
I
shall conclude this long chapter with observing that, though
anciently it was usual to rate wages, first by general laws
extending over the whole kingdom, and afterwards by particular
orders of the justices of peace in every particular county,
both these practices have now gone entirely into disuse. "By
the experience of above four hundred years," says Doctor Burn,
"it seems time to lay aside all endeavours to bring under
strict regulations, what in its own nature seems incapable
of minute limitation; for if all persons in the same kind
of work were to receive equal wages, there would be no emulation,
and no room left for industry or ingenuity."
Particular
Acts of Parliament, however, still attempt sometimes to regulate
wages in particular trades and in particular places. Thus
the 8th of George III prohibits under heavy penalties all
master tailors in London, and five miles round it, from giving,
and their workmen from accepting, more than two shillings
and sevenpence halfpenny a day, except in the case of a general
mourning. Whenever the legislature attempts to regulate the
differences between masters and their workmen, its counsellors
are always the masters. When the regulation, therefore, is
in favour of the workmen, it is always just and equitable;
but it is sometimes otherwise when in favour of the masters.
Thus the law which obliges the masters in several different
trades to pay their workmen in money and not in goods is quite
just and equitable. It imposes no real hardship upon the masters.
It only obliges them to pay that value in money, which they
pretended to pay, but did not always really pay, in goods.
This law is in favour of the workmen: but the 8th of George
III is in favour of the masters. When masters combine together
in order to reduce the wages of their workmen, they commonly
enter into a private bond or agreement not to give more than
a certain wage under a certain penalty. Were the workmen to
enter into a contrary combination of the same kind, not to
accept of a certain wage under a certain penalty, the law
would punish them very severely; and if it dealt impartially,
it would treat the masters in the same manner. But the 8th
of George III enforces by law that very regulation which masters
sometimes attempt to establish by such combinations. The complaint
of the workmen, that it puts the ablest and most industrious
upon the same footing with an ordinary workman, seems perfectly
well founded.
In
ancient times, too, it was usual to attempt to regulate the
profits of merchants and other dealers, by rating the price
both of provisions and other goods. The assize of bread is,
so far as I know, the only remnant of this ancient usage.
Where there is an exclusive corporation, it may perhaps be
proper to regulate the price of the first necessary of life.
But where there is none, the competition will regulate it
much better than any assize. The method of fixing the assize
of bread established by the 31st of George II could not be
put in practice in Scotland, on account of a defect in the
law; its execution depending upon the office of a clerk of
the market, which does not exist there. This defect was not
remedied till the 3rd of George III. The want of an assize
occasioned no sensible inconveniency, and the establishment
of one, in the few places where it has yet taken place, has
produced no sensible advantage. In the greater part of the
towns of Scotland, however, there is an incorporation of bakers
who claim exclusive privileges, though they are not very strictly
guarded.
The
proportion between the different rates both of wages and profit
in the different employments of labour and stock, seems not
to be much affected, as has already been observed, by the
riches or poverty, the advancing, stationary, or declining
state of the society. Such revolutions in the public welfare,
though they affect the general rates both of wages and profit,
must in the end affect them equally in all different employments.
The proportion between them, therefore, must remain the same,
and cannot well be altered, at least for any considerable
time, by any such revolutions.