Rent,
considered as the price paid for the use of land, is naturally
the highest which the tenant can afford to pay in the actual
circumstances of the land. In adjusting the terms of the lease,
the landlord endeavours to leave him no greater share of the
produce than what is sufficient to keep up the stock from
which he furnishes the seed, pays the labour, and purchases
and maintains the cattle and other instruments of husbandry,
together with the ordinary profits of farming stock in the
neighbourhood. This is evidently the smallest share with which
the tenant can content himself without being a loser, and
the landlord seldom means to leave him any more. Whatever
part of the produce, or, what is the same thing, whatever
part of its price is over and above this share, he naturally
endeavours to reserve to himself as the rent of his land,
which is evidently the highest the tenant can afford to pay
in the actual circumstances of the land. Sometimes, indeed,
the liberality, more frequently the ignorance, of the landlord,
makes him accept of somewhat less than this portion; and sometimes
too, though more rarely, the ignorance of the tenant makes
him undertake to pay somewhat more, or to content himself
with somewhat less than the ordinary profits of farming stock
in the neighbourhood. This portion, however, may still be
considered as the natural rent of land, or the rent for which
it is naturally meant that land should for the most part be
let.
The
rent of land, it may be thought, is frequently no more than
a reasonable profit or interest for the stock laid out by
the landlord upon its improvement. This, no doubt, may be
partly the case upon some occasions; for it can scarce ever
be more than partly the case. The landlord demands a rent
even for unimproved land, and the supposed interest or profit
upon the expense of improvement is generally an addition to
this original rent. Those improvements, besides, are not always
made by the stock of the landlord, but sometimes by that of
the tenant. When the lease comes to be renewed, however, the
landlord commonly demands the same augmentation of rent as
if they had been all made by his own.
He
sometimes demands rent for what is altogether incapable of
human improvement. Kelp is a species of sea-weed, which, when
burnt, yields an alkaline salt, useful for making glass, soap,
and for several other purposes. It grows in several parts
of Great Britain, particularly in Scotland, upon such rocks
only as lie within the high water mark, which are twice every
day covered with the sea, and of which the produce, therefore,
was never augmented by human industry. The landlord, however,
whose estate is bounded by a kelp shore of this kind, demands
a rent for it as much as for his corn fields.
The
sea in the neighbourhood of the islands of Shetland is more
than commonly abundant in fish, which makes a great part of
the subsistence of their inhabitants. But in order to profit
by the produce of the water, they must have a habitation upon
the neighbouring land. The rent of the landlord is in proportion,
not to what the farmer can make by the land, but to what he
can make both by the land and by the water. It is partly paid
in sea-fish; and one of the very few instances in which rent
makes a part of the price of that commodity is to be found
in that country.
The
rent of the land, therefore, considered as the price paid
for the use of the land, is naturally a monopoly price. It
is not at all proportioned to what the landlord may have laid
out upon the improvement of the land, or to what he can afford
to take; but to what the farmer can afford to give.
Such
parts only of the produce of land can commonly be brought
to market of which the ordinary price is sufficient to replace
the stock which must be employed in bringing them thither,
together with its ordinary profits. If the ordinary price
is more than this, the surplus part of it will naturally go
to the rent of land. If it is not more, though the commodity
may be brought to market, it can afford no rent to the landlord.
Whether the price is or is not more depends upon the demand.
There
are some parts of the produce of land for which the demand
must always be such as to afford a greater price than what
is sufficient to bring them to market; and there are others
for which it either may or may not be such as to afford this
greater price. The former must always afford a rent to the
landlord. The latter sometimes may, and sometimes may not,
according to different circumstances.
Rent,
it is to be observed, therefore, enters into the composition
of the price of commodities in a different way from wages
and profit. High or low wages and profit are the causes of
high or low price; high or low rent is the effect of it. It
is because high or low wages and profit must be paid, in order
to bring a particular commodity to market, that its price
is high or low. But it is because its price is high or low;
a great deal more, or very little more, or no more, than what
is sufficient to pay those wages and profit, that it affords
a high rent, or a low rent, or no rent at all.
The
particular consideration, first, of those parts of the produce
of land which always afford some rent; secondly, of those
which sometimes may and sometimes may not afford rent; and,
thirdly, of the variations which, in the different periods
of improvement, naturally take place in the relative value
of those two different sorts of rude produce, when compared
both with one another and with manufactured commodities, will
divide this chapter into three parts.
Part
1: Of the Produce of
Land which always affords Rent
As
men, like all other animals, naturally multiply in proportion
to the means of their subsistence, food is always, more or
less, in demand. It can always purchase or command a greater
or smaller quantity of labour, and somebody can always be
found who is willing to do something in order to obtain it.
The quantity of labour, indeed, which it can purchase is not
always equal to what it could maintain, if managed in the
most economical manner, on account of the high wages which
are sometimes given to labour. But it can always purchase
such a quantity of labour as it can maintain, according to
the rate at which the sort of labour is commonly maintained
in the neighbourhood.
But
land, in almost any situation, produces a greater quantity
of food than what is sufficient to maintain all the labour
necessary for bringing it to market in the most liberal way
in which that labour is ever maintained. The surplus, too,
is always more than sufficient to replace the stock which
employed that labour, together with its profits. Something,
therefore, always remains for a rent to the landlord.
The
most desert moors in Norway and Scotland produce some sort
of pasture for cattle, of which the milk and the increase
are always more than sufficient, not only to maintain all
the labour necessary for tending them, and to pay the ordinary
profit to the farmer or owner of the herd or flock; but to
afford some small rent to the landlord. The rent increases
in proportion to the goodness of the pasture. The same extent
of ground not only maintains a greater number of cattle, but
as they are brought within a smaller compass, less labour
becomes requisite to tend them, and to collect their produce.
The landlord gains both ways, by the increase of the produce
and by the diminution of the labour which must be maintained
out of it.
The
rent of land not only varies with its fertility, whatever
be its produce, but with its situation, whatever be its fertility.
Land in the neighbourhood of a town gives a greater rent than
land equally fertile in a distant part of the country. Though
it may cost no more labour to cultivate the one than the other,
it must always cost more to bring the produce of the distant
land to market. A greater quantity of labour, therefore, must
be maintained out of it; and the surplus, from which are drawn
both the profit of the farmer and the rent of the landlord,
must be diminished. But in remote parts of the country the
rate of profits, as has already been shown, is generally higher
than in the neighbourhood of a large town. A smaller proportion
of this diminished surplus, therefore, must belong to the
landlord.
Good
roads, canals, and navigable rivers, by diminishing the expense
of carriage, put the remote parts of the country more nearly
upon a level with those in the neighbourhood of the town.
They are upon that account the greatest of all improvements.
They encourage the cultivation of the remote, which must always
be the most extensive circle of the country. They are advantageous
to the town, by breaking down the monopoly of the country
in its neighbourhood. They are advantageous even to that part
of the country. Though they introduce some rival commodities
into the old market, they open many new markets to its produce.
Monopoly, besides, is a great enemy to good management, which
can never be universally established but in consequence of
that free and universal competition which forces everybody
to have recourse to it for the sake of self-defence. It is
not more than fifty years ago that some of the counties in
the neighbourhood of London petitioned the Parliament against
the extension of the turnpike roads into the remoter counties.
Those remoter counties, they pretended, from the cheapness
of labour, would be able to sell their grass and corn cheaper
in the London market than themselves, and would thereby reduce
their rents, and ruin their cultivation. Their rents, however,
have risen, and their cultivation has been improved since
that time.
A
cornfield of moderate fertility produces a much greater quantity
of food for man than the best pasture of equal extent. Though
its cultivation requires much more labour, yet the surplus
which remains after replacing the seed and maintaining all
that labour, is likewise much greater. If a pound of butcher's
meat, therefore, was never supposed to be worth more than
a pound of bread, this greater surplus would everywhere be
of greater value, and constitute a greater fund both for the
profit of the farmer and the rent of the landlord. It seems
to have done so universally in the rude beginnings of agriculture.
But
the relative values of those two different species of food,
bread and butcher's meat, are very different in the different
periods of agriculture. In its rude beginnings, the unimproved
wilds, which then occupy the far greater part of the country,
are all abandoned to cattle. There is more butcher's meat
than bread, and bread, therefore, is the food for which there
is the greatest competition, and which consequently brings
the greatest price. At Buenos Ayres, we are told by Ulloa,
four reals, one-and-twenty pence halfpenny sterling, was,
forty or fifty years ago, the ordinary price of an ox, chosen
from a herd of two or three hundred. He says nothing of the
price of bread, probably because he found nothing remarkable
about it. An ox there, he says, cost little more than the
labour of catching him. But corn can nowhere be raised without
a great deal of labour, and in a country which lies upon the
river Plate, at that time the direct road from Europe to the
silver mines of Potosi, the money price of labour could not
be very cheap. It is otherwise when cultivation is extended
over the greater part of the country. There is then more bread
than butcher's meat. The competition changes its direction,
and the price of butcher's meat becomes greater than the price
of bread.
By
the extension besides of cultivation, the unimproved wilds
become insufficient to supply the demand for butcher's meat.
A great part of the cultivated lands must be employed in rearing
and fattening cattle, of which the price, therefore, must
be sufficient to pay, not only the labour necessary for tending
them, but the rent which the landlord and the profit which
the farmer could have drawn from such land employed in tillage.
The cattle bred upon the most uncultivated moors, when brought
to the same market, are, in proportion to their weight or
goodness, sold at the same price as those which are reared
upon the most improved land. The proprietors of those moors
profit by it, and raise the rent of their land in proportion
to the price of their cattle. It is not more than a century
ago that in many parts of the highlands of Scotland, butcher's
meat was as cheap or cheaper than even bread made of oatmeal.
The union opened the market of England to the highland cattle.
Their ordinary price is at present about three times greater
than at the beginning of the century, and the rents of many
highland estates have been tripled and quadrupled in the same
time. In almost every part of Great Britain a pound of the
best butcher's meat is, in the present times, generally worth
more than two pounds of the best white bread; and in plentiful
years it is sometimes worth three or four pounds.
It
is thus that in the progress of improvement the rent and profit
of unimproved pasture come to be regulated in some measure
by the rent and profit of what is improved, and these again
by the rent and profit of corn. Corn is an annual crop. Butcher's
meat, a crop which requires four or five years to grow. As
an acre of land, therefore, will produce a much smaller quantity
of the one species of food than of the other, the inferiority
of the quantity must be compensated by the superiority of
the price. If it was more than compensated, more corn land
would be turned into pasture; and if it was not compensated,
part of what was in pasture would be brought back into corn.
This
equality, however, between the rent and profit of grass and
those of corn; of the land of which the immediate produce
is food for cattle, and of that of which the immediate produce
is food for men; must be understood to take place only through
the greater part of the improved lands of a great country.
In some particular local situations it is quite otherwise,
and the rent and profit of grass are much superior to what
can be made by corn.
Thus
in the neighbourhood of a great town the demand for milk and
for forage to horses frequently contribute, together with
the high price of butcher's meat, to raise the value of grass
above what may be called its natural proportion to that of
corn. This local advantage, it is evident, cannot be communicated
to the lands at a distance.
Particular
circumstances have sometimes rendered some countries so populous
that the whole territory, like the lands in the neighbourhood
of a great town, has not been sufficient to produce both the
grass and the corn necessary for the subsistence of their
inhabitants. Their lands, therefore, have been principally
employed in the production of grass, the more bulky commodity,
and which cannot be so easily brought from a great distance;
and corn, the food of the great body of the people, has been
chiefly imported from foreign countries. Holland is at present
in this situation, and a considerable part of ancient Italy
seems to have been so during the prosperity of the Romans.
To feed well, old Cato said, as we are told by Cicero, was
the first and most profitable thing in the management of a
private estate; to feed tolerably well, the second; and to
feed ill, the third. To plough, he ranked only in the fourth
place of profit and advantage. Tillage, indeed, in that part
of ancient Italy which lay in the neighbourhood of Rome, must
have been very much discouraged by the distributions of corn
which were frequently made to the people, either gratuitously,
or at a very low price. This corn was brought from the conquered
provinces, of which several, instead of taxes, were obliged
to furnish a tenth part of their produce at a stated price,
about sixpence a peck, to the republic. The low price at which
this corn was distributed to the people must necessarily have
sunk the price of what could be brought to the Roman market
from Latium, or the ancient territory of Rome, and must have
discouraged its cultivation in that country.
In
an open country too, of which the principal produce is corn,
a well-enclosed piece of grass will frequently rent higher
than any corn field in its neighbourhood. It is convenient
for the maintenance of the cattle employed in the cultivation
of the corn, and its high rent is, in this case, not so properly
paid from the value of its own produce as from that of the
corn lands which are cultivated by means of it. It is likely
to fall, if ever the neighbouring lands are completely enclosed.
The present high rent of enclosed land in Scotland seems owing
to the scarcity of enclosure, and will probably last no longer
than that scarcity. The advantage of enclosure is greater
for pasture than for corn. It saves the labour of guarding
the cattle, which feed better, too, when they are not liable
to be disturbed by their keeper or his dog.
But
where there is no local advantage of this kind, the rent and
profit of corn, or whatever else is the common vegetable food
or the people, must naturally regulate, upon the land which
is fit for producing it, the rent and profit of pasture.
The
use of the artificial grasses, of turnips, carrots, cabbages,
and the other expedients which have been fallen upon to make
an equal quantity of land feed a greater number of cattle
than when in natural grass, should somewhat reduce, it might
be expected, the superiority which, in an improved country,
the price of butcher's meat naturally has over that of bread.
It seems accordingly to have done so; and there is some reason
for believing that, at least in the London market, the price
of butcher's meat in proportion to the price of bread is a
good deal lower in the present times than it was in the beginning
of the last century.
In
the appendix to the Life of Prince Henry, Doctor Birch has
given us an account of the prices of butcher's meat as commonly
paid by that prince. It is there said that the four quarters
of an ox weighing six hundred pounds usually cost him nine
pounds ten shillings, or thereabouts; that is, thirty-one
shillings and eightpence per hundred pounds weight. Prince
Henry died on the 6th of November 1612, in the nineteenth
year of his age.
In
March 1764, there was a Parliamentary inquiry into the causes
of the high price of provisions at that time. It was then,
among other proof to the same purpose, given in evidence by
a Virginia merchant, that in March 1763, he had victualled
his ships for twenty-four or twenty-five shillings the hundredweight
of beef, which he considered as the ordinary price; whereas,
in that dear year, he had paid twenty-seven shillings for
the same weight and sort. This high price in 1764 is, however,
four shillings and eightpence cheaper than the ordinary price
paid by Prince Henry; and it is the best beef only, it must
be observed, which is fit to be salted for those distant voyages.
The
price paid by Prince Henry amounts to 3 3/4d. per pound weight
of the whole carcase, coarse and choice pieces taken together;
and at that rate the choice pieces could not have been sold
by retail for less than 4 1/2d. or 5d. the pound.
In
the Parliamentary inquiry in 1764, the witnesses stated the
price of the choice pieces of the best beef to be to the consumer
4d. and 4 1/4d. the pound; and the coarse pieces in general
to be from seven farthings to 2 1/2d. and this they said was
in general one halfpenny dearer than the same sort of pieces
had usually been sold in the month of March. But even this
high price is still a good deal cheaper than what we can well
suppose the ordinary retail price to have been the time of
Prince Henry.
During
the twelve first years of the last century, the average price
of the best wheat at the Windsor market was L1 18s. 3 1/6d.
the quarter of nine Winchester bushels.
But
in the twelve years preceding 1764, including that year, the
average price of the same measure of the best wheat at the
same market was L2 1s. 9 1/2d.
In
the twelve first years of the last century, therefore, wheat
appears to have been a good deal cheaper, and butcher's meat
a good deal dearer, than in the twelve years preceding 1764,
including that year.
In
all great countries the greater part of the cultivated lands
are employed in producing either food for men or food for
cattle. The rent and profit of these regulate the rent and
profit of all other cultivated land. If any particular produce
afforded less, the land would soon be turned into corn or
pasture; and if any afforded more, some part of the lands
in corn or pasture would soon be turned to that produce.
Those
productions, indeed, which require either a greater original
expense of improvement, or a greater annual expense of cultivation,
in order to fit the land for them, appear commonly to afford,
the one a greater rent, the other a greater profit than corn
or pasture. This superiority, however, will seldom be found
to amount to more than a reasonable interest or compensation
for this superior expense.
In
a hop garden, a fruit garden, a kitchen garden, both the rent
of the landlord, and the profit of the farmer, are generally
greater than in a corn or grass field. But to bring the ground
into this condition requires more expense. Hence a greater
rent becomes due to the landlord. It requires, too, a more
attentive and skilful management. Hence a greater profit becomes
due to the farmer. The crop too, at least in the hop and fruit
garden, is more precarious. Its price, therefore, besides
compensating all occasional losses, must afford something
like the profit of insurance. The circumstances of gardeners,
generally mean, and always moderate, may satisfy us that their
great ingenuity is not commonly over-recompensed. Their delightful
art is practised by so many rich people for amusement, that
little advantage is to be made by those who practise it for
profit; because the persons who should naturally be their
best customers supply themselves with all their most precious
productions.
The
advantage which the landlord derives from such improvements
seems at no time to have been greater than what was sufficient
to compensate the original expense of making them. In the
ancient husbandry, after the vineyard, a well-watered kitchen
garden seems to have been the part of the farm which was supposed
to yield the most valuable produce. But Democritus, who wrote
upon husbandry about two thousand years ago, and who was regarded
by the ancients as one of the fathers of the art, thought
they did not act wisely who enclosed a kitchen garden. The
profit, he said, would not compensate the expense of a stone
wall; and bricks (he meant, I suppose, bricks baked in the
sun) mouldered with the rain, and the winter storm, and required
continual repairs. Columella, who reports this judgment of
Democritus, does not controvert it, but proposes a very frugal
method of enclosing with a hedge of brambles and briars, which,
he says, he had found by experience to be both a lasting and
an impenetrable fence; but which, it seems, was not commonly
known in the time of Democritus. Palladius adopts the opinion
of Columella, which had before been recommended by Varro.
In the judgment of those ancient improvers, the produce of
a kitchen garden had, it seems, been little more than sufficient
to pay the extraordinary culture and the expense of watering;
for in countries so near the sun, it was thought proper, in
those times as in the present, to have the command of a stream
of water which could be conducted to every bed in the garden.
Through the greater part of Europe a kitchen garden is not
at present supposed to deserve a better enclosure than that
recommended by Columella. In Great Britain, and some other
northern countries, the finer fruits cannot be brought to
perfection but by the assistance of a wall. Their price, therefore,
in such countries must be sufficient to pay the expense of
building and maintaining what they cannot be had without.
The fruit-wall frequently surrounds the kitchen garden, which
thus enjoys the benefit of an enclosure which its own produce
could seldom pay for.
That
the vineyard, when properly planted and brought to perfection,
was the most valuable part of the farm, seems to have been
an undoubted maxim in the ancient agriculture, as it is in
the modern through all the wine countries. But whether it
was advantageous to plant a new vineyard was a matter of dispute
among the ancient Italian husbandmen, as we learn from Columella.
He decides, like a true lover of all curious cultivation,
in favour of the vineyard, and endeavours to show, by a comparison
of the profit and expense, that it was a most advantageous
improvement. Such comparisons, however, between the profit
and expense of new projects are commonly very fallacious,
and in nothing more so than in agriculture. Had the gain actually
made by such plantations been commonly as great as he imagined
it might have been, there could have been no dispute about
it. The same point is frequently at this day a matter of controversy
in the wine countries. Their writers on agriculture, indeed,
the lovers and promoters of high cultivation, seem generally
disposed to decide with Columella in favour of the vineyard.
In France the anxiety of the proprietors of the old vineyards
to prevent the planting of any new ones, seems to favour their
opinion, and to indicate a consciousness in those who must
have the experience that this species of cultivation is at
present in that country more profitable than any other. It
seems at the same time, however, to indicate another opinion,
that this superior profit can last no longer than the laws
which at present restrain the free cultivation of the vine.
In 1731, they obtained an order of council prohibiting both
the planting of new vineyards and the renewal of those old
ones, of which the cultivation had been interrupted for two
years, without a particular permission from the king, to be
granted only in consequence of an information from the intendant
of the province, certifying that he had examined the land,
and that it was incapable of any other culture. The pretence
of this order was the scarcity of corn and pasture, and the
superabundance of wine. But had this superabundance been real,
it would, without any order of council, have effectually prevented
the plantation of new vineyards, by reducing the profits of
this species of cultivation below their natural proportion
to those of corn and pasture. With regard to the supposed
scarcity of corn, occasioned by the multiplication of vineyards,
corn is nowhere in France more carefully cultivated than in
the wine provinces, where the land is fit for producing it;
as in Burgundy, Guienne, and the Upper Languedoc. The numerous
hands employed in the one species of cultivation necessarily
encourage the other, by affording a ready market for its produce.
To diminish the number of those who are capable of paying
for it is surely a most unpromising expedient for encouraging
the cultivation of corn. It is like the policy which would
promote agriculture by discouraging manufactures.
The
rent and profit of those productions, therefore, which require
either a greater original expense of improvement in order
to fit the land for them, or a greater annual expense of cultivation,
though often much superior to those of corn and pasture, yet
when they do no more than compensate such extraordinary expense,
are in reality regulated by the rent and profit of those common
crops.
It
sometimes happens, indeed, that the quantity of land, which
can be fitted for some particular produce, is too small to
supply the effectual demand. The whole produce can be disposed
of to those who are willing to give somewhat more than what
is sufficient to pay the whole rent, wages, and profit necessary
for raising and bringing it to market, according to their
natural rates, or according to the rates at which they are
paid in the greater part of other cultivated land. The surplus
part of the price which remains after defraying the whole
expense of improvement and cultivation may commonly, in this
case, and in this case only, bear no regular proportion to
the like surplus in corn or pasture, but may exceed it in
almost any degree; and the greater part of this excess naturally
goes to the rent of the landlord.
The
usual and natural proportion, for example, between the rent
and profit of wine and those of corn and pasture must be understood
to take place only with regard to those vineyards which produce
nothing but good common wine, such as can be raised almost
anywhere, upon any light, gravelly, or sandy soil, and which
has nothing to recommend it but its strength and wholesomeness.
It is with such vineyards only that the common land of the
country can be brought into competition; for with those of
a peculiar quality it is evident that it cannot.
The
vine is more affected by the difference of soils than any
other fruit tree. From some it derives a flavour which no
culture or management can equal, it is supposed, upon any
other. This flavour, real or imaginary, is sometimes peculiar
to the produce of a few vineyards; sometimes it extends through
the greater part of a small district, and sometimes through
a considerable part of a large province. The whole quantity
of such wines that is brought to market falls short of the
effectual demand, or the demand of those who would be willing
to pay the whole rent, profit, and wages, necessary for preparing
and bringing them thither, according to the ordinary rate,
or according to the rate at which they are paid in common
vineyards. The whole quantity, therefore, can be disposed
of to those who are willing to pay more, which necessarily
raises the price above that of common wine. The difference
is greater or less according as the fashionableness and scarcity
of the wine render the competition of the buyers more or less
eager. Whatever it be, the greater part of it goes to the
rent of the landlord. For though such vineyards are in general
more carefully cultivated than most others, the high price
of the wine seems to be not so much the effect as the cause
of this careful cultivation. In so valuable a produce the
loss occasioned by negligence is so great as to force even
the most careless to attention. A small part of this high
price, therefore, is sufficient to pay the wages of the extraordinary
labour bestowed upon their cultivation, and the profits of
the extraordinary stock which puts that labour into motion.
The
sugar colonies possessed by the European nations in the West
Indies may be compared to those precious vineyards. Their
whole produce falls short of the effectual demand of Europe,
and can be disposed of to those who are willing to give more
than what is sufficient to pay the whole rent, profit, and
wages necessary for preparing and bringing it to market, according
to the rate at which they are commonly paid by any other produce.
In Cochin China the finest white sugar commonly sells for
three piasters the quintal, about thirteen shillings and sixpence
of our money, as we are told by Mr. Poivre, a very careful
observer of the agriculture of that country. What is there
called the quintal weighs from a hundred and fifty to two
hundred Paris pounds, or a hundred and seventy-five Paris
pounds at a medium, which reduces the price of the hundred-weight
English to about eight shillings sterling, not a fourth part
of what is commonly paid for the brown or muskavada sugars
imported from our colonies, and not a sixth part of what is
paid for the finest white sugar. The greater part of the cultivated
lands in Cochin China are employed in producing corn and rice,
the food of the great body of the people. The respective prices
of corn, rice, and sugar, are there probably in the natural
proportion, or in that which naturally takes place in the
different crops of the greater part of cultivated land, and
which recompenses the landlord and farmer, as nearly as can
be computed according to what is usually the original expense
of improvement and the annual expense of cultivation. But
in our sugar colonies the price of sugar bears no such proportion
to that of the produce of a rice or corn field either in Europe
or in America. It is commonly said that a sugar planter expects
that the rum and molasses should defray the whole expense
of his cultivation, and that his sugar should be all clear
profit. If this be true, for I pretend not to affirm it, it
is as if a corn farmer expected to defray the expense of his
cultivation with the chaff and the straw, and that the grain
should be all clear profit. We see frequently societies of
merchants in London and other trading town's purchase waste
lands in our sugar colonies, which they expect to improve
and cultivate with profit by means of factors and agents,
notwithstanding the great distance and the uncertain returns
from the defective administration of justice in those countries.
Nobody will attempt to improve and cultivate in the same manner
the most fertile lands of Scotland, Ireland, or the corn provinces
of North America, though from the more exact administration
of justice in these countries more regular returns might be
expected.
In
Virginia and Maryland the cultivation of tobacco is preferred,
as more profitable, to that of corn. Tobacco might be cultivated
with advantage through the greater part of Europe; but in
almost every part of Europe it has become a principal subject
of taxation, and to collect a tax from every different farm
in the country where this plant might happen to be cultivated
would be more difficult, it has been supposed, than to levy
one upon its importation at the custom-house. The cultivation
of tobacco has upon this account been most absurdly prohibited
through the greater part of Europe, which necessarily gives
a sort of monopoly to the countries where it is allowed; and
as Virginia and Maryland produce the greatest quantity of
it, they share largely, though with some competitors, in the
advantage of this monopoly. The cultivation of tobacco, however,
seems not to be so advantageous as that of sugar. I have never
even heard of any tobacco plantation that was improved and
cultivated by the capital of merchants who resided in Great
Britain, and our tobacco colonies send us home no such wealthy
planters as we see frequently arrive from our sugar islands.
Though from the preference given in those colonies to the
cultivation of tobacco above that of corn, it would appear
that the effectual demand of Europe for tobacco is not completely
supplied, it probably is more nearly so than that for sugar;
and though the present price of tobacco is probably more than
sufficient to pay the whole rent, wages, and profit necessary
for preparing and bring it to market, according to the rate
at which they are commonly paid in corn land, it must not
be so much more as the present price of sugar. Our tobacco
planters, accordingly, have shown the same fear of the superabundance
of tobacco which the proprietors of the old vineyards in France
have of the superabundance of wine. By act of assembly they
have restrained its cultivation to six thousand plants, supposed
to yield a thousand weight of tobacco, for every negro between
sixteen and sixty years of age. Such a negro, over and above
this quantity of tobacco, can manage, they reckon, four acres
of Indian corn. To prevent the market from being overstocked,
too, they have sometimes, in plentiful years, we are told
by Dr. Douglas (I suspect he has been ill informed), burnt
a certain quantity of tobacco for every negro, in the same
manner as the Dutch are said to do of spices. If such violent
methods are necessary to keep up the present price of tobacco,
the superior advantage of its culture over that of corn, if
it still has any, will not probably be of long continuance.
It
is in this manner that the rent of the cultivated land, of
which the produce is human food, regulates the rent of the
greater part of other cultivated land. No particular produce
can long afford less; because the land would immediately be
turned to another use. And if any particular produce commonly
affords more, it is because the quantity of land which can
be fitted for it is too small to supply the effectual demand.
In
Europe, corn is the principal produce of land which serves
immediately for human food. Except in particular situations,
therefore, the rent of corn land regulates in Europe that
of all other cultivated land. Britain need envy neither the
vineyards of France nor the olive plantations of Italy. Except
in particular situations, the value of these is regulated
by that of corn, in which the fertility of Britain is not
much inferior to that of either of those two countries.
If
in any country the common and favourite vegetable food of
the people should be drawn from a plant of which the most
common land, with the same or nearly the same culture, produced
a much greater quantity than the most fertile does of corn,
the rent of the landlord, or the surplus quantity of food
which would remain to him, after paying the labour and replacing
the stock of the farmer, together with its ordinary profits,
would necessarily be much greater. Whatever was the rate at
which labour was commonly maintained in that country, this
greater surplus could always maintain a greater quantity of
it, and consequently enable the landlord to purchase or command
a greater quantity of it. The real value of his rent, his
real power and authority, his command of the necessaries and
conveniencies of life with which the labour of other people
could supply him, would necessarily be much greater.
A
rice field produces a much greater quantity of food than the
most fertile corn field. Two crops in the year from thirty
to sixty bushels each, are said to be the ordinary produce
of an acre. Though its cultivation, therefore, requires more
labour, a much greater surplus remains after maintaining all
that labour. In those rice countries, therefore, where rice
is the common and favourite vegetable food of the people,
and where the cultivators are chiefly maintained with it,
a greater share of this greater surplus should belong to the
landlord than in corn countries. In Carolina, where the planters,
as in other British colonies, are generally both farmers and
landlords, and where rent consequently is confounded with
profit, the cultivation of rice is found to be more profitable
than that of corn, though their fields produce only one crop
in the year, and though, from the prevalence of the customs
of Europe, rice is not there the common and favourite vegetable
food of the people.
A
good rice field is a bog at all seasons, and at one season
a bog covered with water. It is unfit either for corn, or
pasture, or vineyard, or, indeed, for any other vegetable
produce that is very useful to men; and the lands which are
fit for those purposes are not fit for rice. Even in the rice
countries, therefore, the rent of rice lands cannot regulate
the rent of the other cultivated land, which can never be
turned to that produce.
The
food produced by a field of potatoes is not inferior in quantity
to that produced by a field of rice, and much superior to
what is produced by a field of wheat. Twelve thousand weight
of potatoes from an acre of land is not a greater produce
than two thousand weight of wheat. The food or solid nourishment,
indeed, which can be drawn from each of those two plants,
is not altogether in proportion to their weight, on account
of the watery nature of potatoes. Allowing, however, half
the weight of this root to go to water, a very large allowance,
such an acre of potatoes will still produce six thousand weight
of solid nourishment, three times the quantity produced by
the acre of wheat. An acre of potatoes is cultivated with
less expense than an acre of wheat; the fallow, which generally
precedes the sowing of wheat, more than compensating the hoeing
and other extraordinary culture which is always given to potatoes.
Should this root ever become in any part of Europe, like rice
in some rice countries, the common and favourite vegetable
food of the people, so as to occupy the same proportion of
the lands in tillage which wheat and other sorts of grain
for human food do at present, the same quantity of cultivated
land would maintain a much greater number of people, and the
labourers being generally fed with potatoes, a greater surplus
would remain after replacing all the stock and maintaining
all the labour employed in cultivation. A greater share of
this surplus, too, would belong to the landlord. Population
would increase, and rents would rise much beyond what they
are at present.
The
land which is fit for potatoes is fit for almost every other
useful vegetable. If they occupied the same proportion of
cultivated land which corn does at present, they would regulate,
in the same manner, the rent of the greater part of other
cultivated land.
In
some parts of Lancashire it is pretended, I have been told,
that bread of oatmeal is a heartier food for labouring people
than wheaten bread, and I have frequently heard the same doctrine
held in Scotland. I am, however, somewhat doubtful of the
truth of it. The common people in Scotland, who are fed with
oatmeal, are in general neither so strong, nor so handsome
as the same rank of people in England who are fed with wheaten
bread. They neither work so well, nor look so well; and as
there is not the same difference between the people of fashion
in the two countries, experience would seem to show that the
food of the common people in Scotland is not so suitable to
the human constitution as that of their neighbours of the
same rank in England. But it seems to be otherwise with potatoes.
The chairmen, porters, and coalheavers in London, and those
unfortunate women who live by prostitution, the strongest
men and the most beautiful women perhaps in the British dominions,
are said to be the greater part of them from the lowest rank
of people in Ireland, who are generally fed with this root.
No food can afford a more decisive proof of its nourishing
quality, or of its being peculiarly suitable to the health
of the human constitution.
It
is difficult to preserve potatoes through the year, and impossible
to store them like corn, for two or three years together.
The fear of not being able to sell them before they rot discourages
their cultivation, and is, perhaps, the chief obstacle to
their ever becoming in any great country, like bread, the
principal vegetable food of all the different ranks of the
people.
Part
2: Of the Produce of Land which sometimes
does, and sometimes does not, afford Rent
Human
food seems to be the only produce of land which always and
necessarily affords some rent to the landlord. Other sorts
of produce sometimes may and sometimes may not, according
to different circumstances.
After
food, clothing and lodging are the two great wants of mankind.
Land
in its original rude state can afford the materials of clothing
and lodging to a much greater number of people than it can
feed. In its improved state it can sometimes feed a greater
number of people than it can supply with those materials;
at least in the way in which they require them, and are willing
to pay for them. In the one state, therefore, there is always
a superabundance of those materials, which are frequently,
upon that account, of little or no value. In the other there
is often a scarcity, which necessarily augments their value.
In the one state a great part of them is thrown away as useless,
and the price of what is used is considered as equal only
to the labour and expense of fitting it for use, and can,
therefore, afford no rent to the landlord. In the other they
are all made use of, and there is frequently a demand for
more than can be had. Somebody is always willing to give more
for every part of them than what is sufficient to pay the
expense of bringing them to market. Their price, therefore,
can always afford some rent to the landlord.
The
skins of the larger animals were the original materials of
clothing. Among nations of hunters and shepherds, therefore,
whose food consists chiefly in the flesh of those animals,
every man, by providing himself with food, provides himself
with the materials of more clothing than he can wear. If there
was no foreign commerce, the greater part of them would be
thrown away as things of no value. This was probably the case
among the hunting nations of North America before their country
was discovered by the Europeans, with whom they now exchange
their surplus peltry for blankets, fire-arms, and brandy,
which gives it some value. In the present commercial state
of the known world, the most barbarous nations, I believe,
among whom land property is established, have some foreign
commerce of this kind, and find among their wealthier neighbours
such a demand for all the materials of clothing which their
land produces, and which can neither be wrought up nor consumed
at home, as raises their price above what it costs to send
them to those wealthier neighbours. It affords, therefore,
some rent to the landlord. When the greater part of the highland
cattle were consumed on their own hills, the exportation of
their hides made the most considerable article of the commerce
of that country, and what they were exchanged for afforded
some addition to the rent of the highland estates. The wool
of England, which in old times could neither be consumed nor
wrought up at home, found a market in the then wealthier and
more industrious country of Flanders, and its price afforded
something to the rent of the land which produced it. In countries
not better cultivated than England was then, or than the highlands
of Scotland are now, and which had no foreign commerce, the
materials of clothing would evidently be so superabundant
that a great part of them would be thrown away as useless,
and no part could afford any rent to the landlord.
The
materials of lodging cannot always be transported to so great
a distance as those of clothing, and do not so readily become
an object of foreign commerce. When they are superabundant
in the country which produces them, it frequently happens,
even in the present commercial state of the world, that they
are of no value to the landlord. A good stone quarry in the
neighbourhood of London would afford a considerable rent.
In many parts of Scotland and Wales it affords none. Barren
timber for building is of great value in a populous and well-cultivated
country, and the land which produces it affords a considerable
rent. But in many parts of North America the landlord would
be much obliged to anybody who would carry away the greater
part of his large trees. In some parts of the highlands of
Scotland the bark is the only part of the wood which, for
want of roads and water-carriage, can be sent to market. The
timber is left to rot upon the ground. When the materials
of lodging are so superabundant, the part made use of is worth
only the labour and expense of fitting it for that use. It
affords no rent to the landlord, who generally grants the
use of it to whoever takes the trouble of asking it. The demand
of wealthier nations, however, sometimes enables him to get
a rent for it. The paving of the streets of London has enabled
the owners of some barren rocks on the coast of Scotland to
draw a rent from what never afforded any before. The woods
of Norway and of the coasts of the Baltic find a market in
many parts of Great Britain which they could not find at home,
and thereby afford some rent to their proprietors.
Countries
are populous not in proportion to the number of people whom
their produce can clothe and lodge, but in proportion to that
of those whom it can feed. When food is provided, it is easy
to find the necessary clothing and lodging. But though these
are at hand, it may often be difficult to find food. In some
parts even of the British dominions what is called a house
may be built by one day's labour of one man. The simplest
species of clothing, the skins of animals, require somewhat
more labour to dress and prepare them for use. They do not,
however, require a great deal. Among savage and barbarous
nations, a hundredth or little more than a hundredth part
of the labour of the whole year will be sufficient to provide
them with such clothing and lodging as satisfy the greater
part of the people. All the other ninety-nine parts are frequently
no more than enough to provide them with food.
But
when by the improvement and cultivation of land the labour
of one family can provide food for two, the labour of half
the society becomes sufficient to provide food for the whole.
The other half, therefore, or at least the greater part of
them, can be employed in providing other things, or in satisfying
the other wants and fancies of mankind. Clothing and lodging,
household furniture, and what is called Equipage, are the
principal objects of the greater part of those wants and fancies.
The rich man consumes no more food than his poor neighbour.
In quality it may be very different, and to select and prepare
it may require more labour and art; but in quantity it is
very nearly the same. But compare the spacious palace and
great wardrobe of the one with the hovel and the few rags
of the other, and you will be sensible that the difference
between their clothing, lodging, and household furniture is
almost as great in quantity as it is in quality. The desire
of food is limited in every man by the narrow capacity of
the human stomach; but the desire of the conveniences and
ornaments of building, dress, equipage, and household furniture,
seems to have no limit or certain boundary. Those, therefore,
who have the command of more food than they themselves can
consume, are always willing to exchange the surplus, or, what
is the same thing, the price of it, for gratifications of
this other kind. What is over and above satisfying the limited
desire is given for the amusement of those desires which cannot
be satisfied, but seem to be altogether endless. The poor,
in order to obtain food, exert themselves to gratify those
fancies of the rich, and to obtain it more certainly they
vie with one another in the cheapness and perfection of their
work. The number of workmen increases with the increasing
quantity of food, or with the growing improvement and cultivation
of the lands; and as the nature of their business admits of
the utmost subdivisions of labour, the quantity of materials
which they can work up increases in a much greater proportion
than their numbers. Hence arises a demand for every sort of
material which human invention can employ, either usefully
or ornamentally, in building, dress, equipage, or household
furniture; for the fossils and minerals contained in the bowels
of the earth; the precious metals, and the precious stones.
Food
is in this manner not only the original source of rent, but
every other part of the produce of land which afterwards affords
rent derives that part of its value from the improvement of
the powers of labour in producing food by means of the improvement
and cultivation of land.
Those
other parts of the produce of land, however, which afterwards
afford rent, do not afford it always. Even in improved and
cultivated countries, the demand for them is not always such
as to afford a greater price than what is sufficient to pay
the labour, and replace, together with it ordinary profits,
the stock which must be employed in bringing them to market.
Whether it is or is not such depends upon different circumstances.
Whether
a coal-mine, for example, can afford any rent depends partly
upon its fertility, and partly upon its situation.
A
mine of any kind may be said to be either fertile or barren,
according as the quantity of mineral which can be brought
from it by a certain quantity of labour is greater or less
than what can be brought by an equal quantity from the greater
part of other mines of the same kind.
Some
coal-mines advantageously situated cannot be wrought on account
of their barrenness. The produce does not pay the expense.
They can afford neither profit nor rent.
There
are some of which the produce is barely sufficient to pay
the labour, and replace, together with it ordinary profits,
the stock employed in working them. They afford some profit
to the undertaker of the work, but no rent to the landlord.
They can be wrought advantageously by nobody but the landlord,
who, being himself undertaker of the work, gets the ordinary
profit of the capital which he employs in it. Many coal-mines
in Scotland are wrought in this manner, and can be wrought
in no other. The landlord will allow nobody else to work them
without paying some rent, and nobody can afford to pay any.
Other
coal-mines in the same country, sufficiently fertile, cannot
be wrought on account of their situation. A quantity of mineral
sufficient to defray the expense of working could be brought
from the mine by the ordinary, or even less than the ordinary,
quantity of labour; but in an inland country, thinly inhabited,
and without either good roads or water-carriage, this quantity
could not be sold.
Coals
are a less agreeable fuel than wood: they are said, too, to
be less wholesome. The expense of coals, therefore, at the
place where they are consumed, must generally be somewhat
less than that of wood.
The
price of wood again varies with the state of agriculture,
nearly in the same manner, and exactly for the same reason,
as the price of cattle. In its rude beginnings the greater
part of every country is covered with wood, which is then
a mere encumberance of no value to the landlord, who would
gladly give it to anybody for the cutting. As agriculture
advances, the woods are partly cleared by the progress of
tillage, and partly go to decay in consequence of the increased
number of cattle. These, though they do not increase in the
same proportion as corn, which is altogether the acquisition
of human industry, yet multiply under the care and protection
of men, who store up in the season of plenty what may maintain
them in that of scarcity, who through the whole year furnish
them with a greater quantity of food than uncultivated nature
provides for them, and who by destroying and extirpating their
enemies, secure them in the free enjoyment of all that she
provides. Numerous herds of cattle, when allowed to wander
through the woods, though they do not destroy the old trees,
hinder any young ones from coming up so that in the course
of a century or two the whole forest goes to ruin. The scarcity
of wood then raises its price. It affords a good rent, and
the landlord sometimes finds that he can scarce employ his
best lands more advantageously than in growing barren timber,
of which the greatness of the profit often compensates the
lateness of the returns. This seems in the present times to
be nearly the state of things in several parts of Great Britain,
where the profit of planting is found to be equal to that
of either corn or pasture. The advantage which the landlord
derives from planting can nowhere exceed, at least for any
considerable time, the rent which these could afford him;
and in an inland country which is highly cultivated, it will
frequently not fall much short of this rent. Upon the sea-coast
of a well improved country, indeed, if coals can conveniently
be had for fuel, it may sometimes be cheaper to bring barren
timber for building from less cultivated foreign countries
than to raise it at home. In the new town of Edinburgh, built
within these few years, there is not, perhaps, a single stick
of Scotch timber.
Whatever
may be the price of wood, if that of coals is such that the
expense of a coal fire is nearly equal to that of a wood one,
we may be assured that at that place, and in these circumstances,
the price of coals is as high as it can be. It seems to be
so in some of the inland parts of England, particularly in
Oxfordshire, where it is usual, even in the fires of the common
people, to mix coals and wood together, and where the difference
in the expense of those two sorts of fuel cannot, therefore,
be very great.
Coals,
in the coal countries, are everywhere much below this highest
price. If they were not, they could not bear the expense of
a distant carriage, either by land or by water. A small quantity
only could be sold, and the coal masters and coal proprietors
find it more for their interest to sell a great quantity at
a price somewhat above the lowest, than a small quantity at
the highest. The most fertile coal-mine, too, regulates the
price of coals at all the other mines in its neighbourhood.
Both the proprietor and the undertaker of the work find, the
one that he can get a greater rent, the other that he can
get a greater profit, by somewhat underselling all their neighbours.
Their neighbours are soon obliged to sell at the same price,
though they cannot so well afford it, and though it always
diminishes, and sometimes takes away altogether both their
rent and their profit. Some works are abandoned altogether;
others can afford no rent, and can be wrought only by the
proprietor.
The
lowest price at which coals can be sold for any considerable
time is, like that of all other commodities, the price which
is barely sufficient to replace, together with its ordinary
profits, the stock which must be employed in bringing them
to market. At as coal-mine for which the landlord can get
no rent, but which he must either work himself or let it alone
altogether, the price of coals must generally be nearly about
this price.
Rent,
even where coals afford one, has generally a smaller share
in their prices than in that of most other parts of the rude
produce of land. The rent of an estate above ground commonly
amounts to what is supposed to be a third of the gross produce;
and it is generally a rent certain and independent of the
occasional variations in the crop. In coal-mines a fifth of
the gross produce is a very great rent; a tenth the common
rent, and it is seldom a rent certain, but depends upon the
occasional variations in the produce. These are so great that,
in a country where thirty years' purchase is considered as
a moderate price for the property of a landed estate, ten
years' purchase is regarded as a good price for that of a
coal-mine.
The
value of a coal-mine to the proprietor frequently depends
as much upon its situation as upon its fertility. That of
a metallic mine depends more upon its fertility, and less
upon its situation. The coarse, and still more the precious
metals, when separated from the ore, are so valuable that
they can generally bear the expense of a very long land, and
of the most distant sea carriage. Their market is not confined
to the countries in the neighbourhood of the mine, but extends
to the whole world. The copper of Japan makes an article of
commerce in Europe; the iron of Spain in that of Chili and
Peru. The silver of Peru finds its way, not only to Europe,
but from Europe to China.
The
price of coals in Westmoreland or Shropshire can have little
effect on their price at Newcastle; and their price in the
Lionnois can have none at all. The productions of such distant
coal-mines can never be brought into competition with one
another. But the productions of the most distant metallic
mines frequently may, and in fact commonly are. The price,
therefore, of the coarse, and still more that of the precious
metals, at the most fertile mines in the world, must necessarily
more or less affect their price at every other in it. The
price of copper in Japan must have some influence upon its
price at the copper mines in Europe. The price of silver in
Peru, or the quantity either of labour or of other goods which
it will purchase there, must have some influence on its price,
not only at the silver mines of Europe, but at those of China.
After the discovery of the mines of Peru, the silver mines
of Europe were, the greater part of them, abandoned. The value
of was so much reduced that their produce could no longer
pay the expense of working them, or replace, with a profit,
the food, clothes, lodging, and other necessaries which were
consumed in that operation. This was the case, too, with the
mines of Cuba and St. Domingo, and even with the ancient mines
of Peru, after the discovery of those of Potosi.
The
price of every metal at every mine, therefore, being regulated
in some measure by its price at the most fertile mine in the
world that is actually wrought, it can at the greater part
of mines do very little more than pay the expense of working,
and can seldom afford a very high rent to the landlord. Rent,
accordingly, seems at the greater part of mines to have but
a small share in the price of the coarse, and a still smaller
in that of the precious metals. Labour and profit make up
the greater part of both.
A
sixth part of the gross produce may be reckoned the average
rent of the tin mines of Cornwall the most fertile that are
known in the world, as we are told by the Reverend Mr. Borlace,
vice-warden of the stannaries. Some, he says, afford more,
and some do not afford so much. A sixth part of the gross
produce is the rent, too, of several very fertile lead mines
in Scotland.
In
the silver mines of Peru, we are told by Frezier and Ulloa,
the proprietor frequently exacts no other acknowledgment from
the undertaker of the mine, but that he will grind the ore
at his mill, paying him the ordinary multure or price of grinding.
Till 1736, indeed, the tax of the King of Spain amounted to
one-fifth of the standard silver, which till then might be
considered as the real rent of the greater part of the silver
mines of Peru, the richest which have been known in the world.
If there had been no tax this fifth would naturally have belonged
to the landlord, and many mines might have been wrought which
could not then be wrought, because they could not afford this
tax. The tax of the Duke of Cornwall upon tin is supposed
to amount to more than five per cent or one-twentieth part
of the value, and whatever may be his proportion, it would
naturally, too, belong to the proprietor of the mine, if tin
was duty free. But if you add one-twentieth to one-sixth,
you will find that the whole average rent of the tin mines
of Cornwall was to the whole average rent of the silver mines
of Peru as thirteen to twelve. But the silver mines of Peru
are not now able to pay even this low rent, and the tax upon
silver was, in 1736, reduced from one-fifth to one-tenth.
Even this tax upon silver, too, gives more temptation to smuggling
than the tax of one-twentieth upon tin; and smuggling must
be much easier in the precious than in the bulky commodity.
The tax of the King of Spain accordingly is said to be very
ill paid, and that of the Duke of Cornwall very well. Rent,
therefore, it is probable, makes a greater part of the price
of tin at the most fertile tin mines than it does of silver
at the most fertile silver mines in the world. After replacing
the stock employed in working those different mines, together
with its ordinary profits, the residue which remains to the
proprietor is greater, it seems, in the coarse than in the
precious metal.
Neither
are the profits of the undertakers of silver mines commonly
very great in Peru. The same most respectable and well-informed
authors acquaint us, that when any person undertakes to work
a new mine in Peru, he is universally looked upon as a man
destined to bankruptcy and ruin, and is upon that account
shunned and avoided by everybody. Mining, it seems, is considered
there in the same light as here, as a lottery, in which the
prizes do not compensate the blanks, though the greatness
of some tempts many adventurers to throw away their fortunes
in such unprosperous projects.
As
the sovereign, however, derives a considerable part of his
revenue from the produce of silver mines, the law in Peru
gives every possible encouragement to the discovery and working
of new ones. Whoever discovers a new mine is entitled to measure
off two hundred and forty-six feet in length, according to
what he supposes to be the direction of the vein, and half
as much in breadth. He becomes proprietor of this portion
of the mine, and can work it without paying any acknowledgment
to the landlord. The interest of the Duke of Cornwall has
given occasion to a regulation nearly of the same kind in
that ancient duchy. In waste and unenclosed lands any person
who discovers a tin mine may mark its limits to a certain
extent, which is called bounding a mine. The bounder becomes
the real proprietor of the mine, and may either work it himself,
or give it in lease to another, without the consent of the
owner of the land, to whom, however, a very small acknowledgment
must be paid upon working it. In both regulations the sacred
rights of private property are sacrificed to the supposed
interests of public revenue.
The
same encouragement is given in Peru to the discovery and working
of new gold mines; and in gold the king's tax amounts only
to a twentieth part of the standard metal. It was once a fifth,
and afterwards a tenth, as in silver; but it was found that
the work could not bear even the lowest of these two taxes.
If it is rare, however, say the same authors, Frezier and
Ulloa, to find a person who has made his fortune by a silver,
it is still much rarer to find one who has done so by a gold
mine. This twentieth part seems to be the whole rent which
is paid by the greater part of the gold mines in Chili and
Peru. Gold, too, is much more liable to be smuggled than even
silver; not only on account of the superior value of the metal
in proportion to its bulk, but on account of the peculiar
way in which nature produces it. Silver is very seldom found
virgin, but, like most other metals, is generally mineralized
with some other body, from which it is impossible to separate
it in such quantities as will pay for the expense, but by
a very laborious and tedious operation, which cannot well
be carried on but in workhouses erected for the purpose, and
therefore exposed to the inspection of the king's officers.
Gold, on the contrary, is almost always found virgin. It is
sometimes found in pieces of some bulk; and even when mixed
in small and almost insensible particles with sand, earth,
and other extraneous bodies, it can be separated from them
by a very short and simple operation, which can be carried
on in any private house by anybody who is possessed of a small
quantity of mercury. If the king's tax, therefore, is but
ill paid upon silver, it is likely to be much worse paid upon
gold; and rent, must make a much smaller part of the price
of gold than even of that of silver.
The
lowest price at which the precious metals can be sold, or
the smallest quantity of other goods for which they can be
exchanged during any considerable time, is regulated by the
same principles which fix the lowest ordinary price of all
other goods. The stock which must commonly be employed, the
food, the clothes, and lodging which must commonly be consumed
in bringing them from the mine to the market, determine it.
It must at least be sufficient to replace that stock, with
the ordinary profits.
Their
highest price, however, seems not to be necessarily determined
by anything but the actual scarcity or plenty of those metals
themselves. It is not determined by that of any other commodity,
in the same manner as the price of coals is by that of wood,
beyond which no scarcity can ever raise it. Increase the scarcity
of gold to a certain degree, and the smallest bit of it may
become more precious than a diamond, and exchange for a greater
quantity of other goods.
The
demand for those metals arises partly from their utility and
partly from their beauty. If you except iron, they are more
useful than, perhaps, any other metal. As they are less liable
to rust and impurity, they can more easily be kept clean,
and the utensils either of the table or the kitchen are often
upon that account more agreeable when made of them. A silver
boiler is more cleanly than a lead, copper, or tin one; and
the same quality would render a gold boiler still better than
a silver one. Their principal merit, however, arises from
their beauty, which renders them peculiarly fit for the ornaments
of dress and furniture. No paint or dye can give so splendid
a colour as gilding. The merit of their beauty is greatly
enhanced by their scarcity. With the greater part of rich
people, the chief enjoyment of riches consists in the parade
of riches, which in their eye is never so complete as when
they appear to possess those decisive marks of opulence which
nobody can possess but themselves. In their eyes the merit
of an object which is in any degree either useful or beautiful
is greatly enhanced by its scarcity, or by the great labour
which it requires to collect any considerable quantity of
it, a labour which nobody can afford to pay but themselves.
Such objects they are willing to purchase at a higher price
than things much more beautiful and useful, but more common.
These qualities of utility, beauty, and scarcity, are the
original foundation of the high price of those metals, or
of the great quantity of other goods for which they can everywhere
be exchanged. This value was antecedent to and independent
of their being employed as coin, and was the quality which
fitted them for that employment. That employment, however,
by occasioning a new demand, and by diminishing the quantity
which could be employed in any other way, may have afterwards
contributed to keep up or increase their value.
The
demand for the precious stones arises altogether from their
beauty. They are of no use but as ornaments; and the merit
of their beauty is greatly enhanced by their scarcity, or
by the difficulty and expense of getting them from the mine.
Wages and profit accordingly make up, upon most occasions,
almost the whole of their high price. Rent comes in but for
a very small share; frequently for no share; and the most
fertile mines only afford any considerable rent. When Tavernier,
a jeweller, visited the diamond mines of Golconda and Visiapour,
he was informed that the sovereign of the country, for whose
benefit they were wrought, had ordered all of them to be shut
up, except those which yield the largest and finest stones.
The others, it seems, were to the proprietor not worth the
working.
As
the price both of the precious metals and of the precious
stones is regulated all over the world by their price at the
most fertile mine in it, the rent which a mine of either can
afford to its proprietor is in proportion, not to its absolute,
but to what may be called its relative fertility, or to its
superiority over other mines of the same kind. If new mines
were discovered as much superior to those of Potosi as they
were superior to those Europe, the value of silver might be
so much degraded as to render even the mines of Potosi not
worth the working. Before the discovery of the Spanish West
Indies, the most fertile mines in Europe may have afforded
as great a rent to their proprietor as the richest mines in
Peru do at present. Though the quantity of silver was much
less, it might have exchanged for an equal quantity of other
goods, and the proprietor's share might have enabled him to
purchase or command an equal quantity either of labour or
of commodities. The value both of the produce and of the rent,
the real revenue which they afforded both to the public and
to the proprietor, might have been the same.
The
most abundant mines either of the precious metals or of the
precious stones could add little to the wealth of the world.
A produce of which the value is principally derived from its
scarcity, is necessarily degraded by its abundance. A service
of plate, and the other frivolous ornaments of dress and furniture,
could be purchased for a smaller quantity of labour, or for
a smaller quantity of commodities; and in this would consist
the sole advantage which the world could derive from that
abundance.
It
is otherwise in estates above ground. The value both of their
produce and of their rent is in proportion to their absolute,
and not to their relative fertility. The land which produces
a certain quantity of food, clothes, and lodging, can always
feed, clothe, and lodge a certain number of people; and whatever
may be the proportion of the landlord, it will always give
him a proportionable command of the labour of those people,
and of the commodities with which that labour can supply him.
The value of the most barren lands is not diminished by the
neighbourhood of the most fertile. On the contrary, it is
generally increased by it. The great number of people maintained
by the fertile lands afford a market to many parts of the
produce of the barren, which they could never have found among
those whom their own produce could maintain.
Whatever
increases the fertility of land in producing food increases
not only the value of the lands upon which the improvement
is bestowed, but contributes likewise to increase that of
many other lands by creating a new demand for their produce.
That abundance of food, of which, in consequence of the improvement
of land, many people have the disposal beyond what they themselves
can consume, is the great cause of the demand both for the
precious metals and the precious stone, as well as for every
other conveniency and ornament of dress, lodging, household
furniture, and equipage. Food not only constitutes the principal
part of the riches of the world, but it is the abundance of
food which gives the principal part of their value to many
other sorts of riches. The poor inhabitants of Cuba and St.
Domingo, when they were first discovered by the Spaniards,
used to wear little bits of gold as ornaments in their hair
and other parts of their dress. They seemed to value them
as we would do any little pebbles of somewhat more than ordinary
beauty, and to consider them as just worth the picking up,
but not worth the refusing to anybody who asked them. They
gave them to their new guests at the first request, without
seeming to think that they had made them any very valuable
present. They were astonished to observe the rage of the Spaniards
to obtain them; and had no notion that there could anywhere
be a country in which many people had the disposal of so great
a superfluity of food, so scanty always among themselves,
that for a very small quantity of those glittering baubles
they would willingly give as much as might maintain a whole
family for many years. Could they have been made to understand
this, the passion of the Spaniards would not have surprised
them.
Part
3: Of the Variations in the Proportion between the respective
Values
of that Sort of Produce which always affords Rent, and of
that
which sometimes does and sometimes does not afford Rent
The
increasing abundance of food, in consequence of increasing
improvement and cultivation, must necessarily increase the
demand for every part of the produce of land which is not
food, and which can be applied either to use or to ornament.
In the whole progress of improvement, it might therefore be
expected, there should be only one variation in the comparative
values of those two different sorts of produce. The value
of that sort which sometimes does and sometimes does not afford
rent, should constantly rise in proportion to that which always
affords some rent. As art and industry advance, the materials
of clothing and lodging, the useful fossils and minerals of
the earth, the precious metals and the precious stones should
gradually come to be more and more in demand, should gradually
exchange for a greater and a greater quantity of food, or
in other words, should gradually become dearer and dearer.
This accordingly has been the case with most of these things
upon most occasions, and would have been the case with all
of them upon all occasions, if particular accidents had not
upon some occasions increased the supply of some of them in
a still greater proportion than the demand.
The
value of a free-stone quarry, for example, will necessarily
increase with the increasing improvement and population of
the country round about it, especially if it should be the
only one in the neighbourhood. But the value of a silver mine,
even though there should not be another within a thousand
miles of it, will not necessarily increase with the improvement
of the country in which it is situated. The market for the
produce of a freestone quarry can seldom extend more than
a few miles round about it, and the demand must generally
be in proportion to the improvement and population of that
small district. But the market for the produce of a silver
mine may extend over the whole known world. Unless the world
in general, therefore, be advancing in improvement and population,
the demand for silver might not be at all increased by the
improvement even of a large country in the neighbourhood of
the mine. Even though the world in general were improving,
yet if, in the course of its improvement, new mines should
be discovered, much more fertile than any which had been known
before, though the demand for silver would necessarily increase,
yet the supply might increase in so much a greater proportion
that the real price of that metal might gradually fall; that
is, any given quantity, a pound weight of it, for example,
might gradually purchase or command a smaller and a smaller
quantity of labour, or exchange for a smaller and a smaller
quantity of corn, the principal part of the subsistence of
the labourer.
The
great market for silver is the commercial and civilised part
of the world.
If
by the general progress of improvement the demand of this
market should increase, while at the same time the supply
did not increase in the same proportion, the value of silver
would gradually rise in proportion to that of corn. Any given
quantity of silver would exchange for a greater and a greater
quantity of corn; or, in other words, the average money price
of corn would gradually become cheaper and cheaper.
If,
on the contrary, the supply by some accident should increase
for many years together in a greater proportion than the demand,
that metal would gradually become cheaper and cheaper; or,
in other words, the average money price of corn would, in
spite of all improvements, gradually become dearer and dearer.
But
if, on the other hand, the supply of the metal should increase
nearly in the same proportion as the demand, it would continue
to purchase or exchange for nearly the same quantity of corn,
and the average money price of corn would, in spite of all
improvements, continue very nearly the same.
These
three seem to exhaust all the possible combinations of events
which can happen in the progress of improvement; and during
the course of the four centuries preceding the present, if
we may judge by what has happened both in France and Great
Britain, each of those three different combinations seem to
have taken place in the European market, and nearly in the
same order, too, in which I have here set them down.
DIGRESSIONS
CONCERNING THE VARIATIONS
IN THE VALUE OF SILVER DURING THE
COURSE OF THE FOUR LAST CENTURIES
FIRST PERIOD
In
1350, and for some time before, the average price of the quarter
of wheat in England seems not to have been estimated lower
than four ounces of silver, Tower weight, equal to about twenty
shillings of our present money. From this price it seems to
have fallen gradually to two ounces of silver, equal to about
ten shillings of our present money, the price at which we
find it estimated in the beginning of the sixteenth century,
and at which it seems to have continued to be estimated till
about 1570.
In
1350, being the 25th of Edward III, was enacted what is called
The Statute of Labourers. In the preamble it complains much
of the insolence of servants, who endeavoured to raise their
wages upon their masters. It therefore ordains that all servants
and labourers should for the future be contented with the
same wages and liveries (liveries in those times signified
not only clothes but provisions) which they had been accustomed
to receive in the 20th year of the king, and the four preceding
years; that upon this account their livery wheat should nowhere
be estimated higher than tenpence a bushel, and that it should
always be in the option of the master to deliver them either
the wheat or the money. Tenpence a bushel, therefore, had,
in the 25th of Edward III, been reckoned a very moderate price
of wheat, since it required a particular statute to oblige
servants to accept of it in exchange for their usual livery
of provisions; and it had been reckoned a reasonable price
ten years before that, or in the 16th year of the king, the
term to which the statute refers. But in the 16th year of
Edward III, tenpence contained about half an ounce of silver,
Tower weight, and was nearly equal to half-a-crown of our
present money. Four ounces of silver, Tower weight, therefore,
equal to six shillings and eightpence of the money of those
times, and to near twenty shillings of that of the present,
must have been reckoned a moderate price for the quarter of
eight bushels.
This
statute is surely a better evidence of what was reckoned in
those times a moderate price of grain than the prices of some
particular years which have generally been recorded by historians
and other writers on account of their extraordinary dearness
or cheapness, and from which, therefore, it is difficult to
form any judgment concerning what may have been the ordinary
price. There are, besides, other reasons for believing that
in the beginning of the fourteenth century, and for some time
before, the common price of wheat was not less than four ounces
of silver the quarter, and that of other grain in proportion.
In
1309, Ralph de Born, prior of St. Augustine's, Canterbury,
gave a feast upon his installation-day, of which William Thorn
has preserved not only the bill of fare but the prices of
many particulars. In that feast were consumed, first, fifty-three
quarters of wheat, which cost nineteen pounds, or seven shillings
and twopence a quarter, equal to about one-and-twenty shillings
and sixpence of our present money; secondly, fifty-eight quarters
of malt, which cost seventeen pounds ten shillings, or six
shillings a quarter, equal to about eighteen shillings of
our present money; thirdly, twenty quarters of oats, which
cost four pounds, or four shillings a quarter, equal to about
twelve shillings of our present money. The prices of malt
and oats seem here to be higher than their ordinary proportion
to the price of wheat.
These
prices are not recorded on account of their extraordinary
dearness or cheapness, but are mentioned accidentally as the
prices actually paid for large quantities of grain consumed
at a feast which was famous for its magnificence.
In
1262, being the 51st of Henry M, was revived an ancient statute
called The Assize of Bread and Ale, which the king says in
the preamble had been made in the times of his progenitors,
sometime kings of England. It is probably, therefore, as old
at least as the time of his grandfather Henry H, and may have
been as old as the Conquest. It regulates the price of bread
according as the prices of wheat may happen to be, from one
shilling to twenty shillings the quarter of the money of those
times. But statutes of this kind are generally presumed to
provide with equal care for all deviations from the middle
price, for those below it as well as for those above it. Ten
shillings, therefore, containing six ounces of silver, Tower
weight, and equal to about thirty shillings of our present
money, must, upon this supposition, have been reckoned the
middle price of the quarter of wheat when this statute was
first enacted, and must have continued to be so in the 51st
of Henry III. We cannot therefore be very wrong in supposing
that the middle price was not less than one-third of the highest
price at which this statute regulates the price of bread,
or than six shillings and eightpence of the money of those
times, containing four ounces of silver, Tower weight.
From
these different facts, therefore, we seem to have some reason
to conclude that, about the middle of the fourteenth century,
and for a considerable time before, the average or ordinary
price of the quarter of wheat was not supposed to be less
than four ounces of silver, Tower weight.
From
about the middle of the fourteenth to the beginning of the
sixteenth century, what was reckoned the reasonable and moderate,
that is the ordinary or average price of wheat, seems to have
sunk gradually to about one-half of this price; so as at last
to have fallen to about two ounces of silver, Tower weight,
equal to about ten shillings of our present money. It continued
to be estimated at this price till about 1570.
In
the household book of Henry, the fifth Earl of Northumberland,
drawn up in 1512, there are two different estimations of wheat.
In one of them it is computed at six shillings and eightpence
the quarter, in the other at five shillings and eightpence
only. In 1512, six shillings and eightpence contained only
two ounces of silver, Tower weight, and were equal to about
ten shillings of our present money.
From
the 25th of Edward III to the beginning of the reign of Elizabeth,
during the space of more than two hundred years, six shillings
and eightpence, it appears from several different statutes,
had continued to be considered as what is called the moderate
and reasonable, that is the ordinary or average price of wheat.
The quantity of silver, however, contained in that nominal
sum was, during the course of this period, continually diminishing,
in consequence of some alterations which were made in the
coin. But the increase of the value of silver had, it seems,
so far compensated the diminution of the quantity of it contained
in the same nominal sum that the legislature did not think
it worth while to attend to this circumstance.
Thus
in 1436 it was enacted that wheat might be exported without
a licence when the price was so low as six shillings and eightpence;
and in 1463 it was enacted that no wheat should be imported
if the price was not above six shillings and eightpence the
quarter. The legislature had imagined that when the price
was so low there could be no inconveniency in exportation,
but that when it rose higher it became prudent to allow importation.
Six shillings and eightpence, therefore, containing about
the same quantity of silver as thirteen shillings and fourpence
of our present money (one third part less than the same nominal
sum contained in the time of Edward III), had in those times
been considered as what is called the moderate and reasonable
price of wheat.
In
1554, by the 1st and 2nd of Philip and Mary; and in 1558,
by the 1st of Elizabeth, the exportation of wheat was in the
same manner prohibited, whenever the price of the quarter
should exceed six shillings and eightpence, which did not
then contain two pennyworth more silver than the same nominal
sum does at present. But it had soon been found that to restrain
the exportation of wheat till the price was so very low was,
in reality, to prohibit it altogether. In 1562, therefore,
by the 5th of Elizabeth, the exportation of wheat was allowed
from certain ports whenever the price of the quarter should
not exceed ten shillings, containing nearly the same quantity
of silver as the like nominal sum does at present. This price
had at this time, therefore, been considered as what is called
the moderate and reasonable price of wheat. It agrees nearly
with the estimation of the Northumberland book in 1512.
That
in France the average price of grain was, in the same manner,
much lower in the end of the fifteenth and beginning of the
sixteenth century than in the two centuries preceding has
been observed both by Mr. Dupre de St. Maur, and by the elegant
author of the Essay on the police of grain. Its price, during
the same period, had probably sunk in the same manner through
the greater part of Europe.
This
rise in the value of silver in proportion to that of corn,
may either have been owing altogether to the increase of the
demand for that metal, in consequence of increasing improvement
and cultivation, the supply in the meantime continuing the
same as before; or, the demand continuing the same as before,
it may have been owing altogether to the gradual diminution
of the supply; the greater part of the mines which were then
known in the world being much exhausted, and consequently
the expense of working them much increased; or it may have
been owing partly to the other of those two circumstances.
In the end of the fifteenth and beginning of the sixteenth
centuries, the greater part of Europe was approaching towards
a more settled form of government than it had enjoyed for
several ages before. The increase of security would naturally
increase industry and improvement; and the demand for the
precious metals, as well as for every other luxury and ornament,
would naturally increase with the increase of riches. A greater
annual produce would require a greater quantity of coin to
circulate it; and a greater number of rich people would require
a greater quantity of plate and other ornaments of silver.
It is natural to suppose, too, that the greater part of the
mines which then supplied the European market with silver
might be a good deal exhausted, and have become more expensive
in the working. They had been wrought many of them from the
time of the Romans.
It
has been the opinion, however, of the greater part of those
who have written upon the price of commodities in ancient
times that, from the Conquest, perhaps from the invasion of
Julius Caesar till the discovery of the mines of America,
the value of silver was continually diminishing. This opinion
they seem to have been led into, partly by the observations
which they had occasion to make upon the prices both of corn
and of some other parts of the rude produce of land; and partly
by the popular notion that as the quantity of silver naturally
increases in every country with the increase of wealth, so
its value diminishes as its quantity increases.
In
their observations upon the prices of corn, three different
circumstances seem frequently to have misled them.
First,
in ancient times almost all rents were paid in kind; in a
certain quantity of corn, cattle, poultry, etc. It sometimes
happened, however, that the landlord would stipulate that
he should be at liberty to demand of the tenant, either the
annual payment in kind, or a certain sum of money instead
of it. The price at which the payment in kind was in this
manner exchanged for a certain sum of money is in Scotland
called the conversion price. As the option is always in the
landlord to take either the substance or the price, it is
necessary for the safety of the tenant that the conversion
price should rather be below than above the average market
price. In many places, accordingly, it is not much above one-half
of this price. Through the greater part of Scotland this custom
still continues with regard to poultry, and in some places
with regard to cattle. It might probably have continued to
take place, too, with regard to corn, had not the institution
of the public fiars put an end to it. These are annual valuations,
according to the judgment of an assize, of the average price
of all the different sorts of grain, and of all the different
qualities of each, according to the actual market price in
every different county. This institution rendered it sufficiently
safe for the tenant, and much more convenient for the landlord,
to convert, as they call it, the corn rent, rather at what
should happen to be the price of the fiars of each year, than
at any certain fixed price. But the writers who have collected
the prices of corn in ancient times seem frequently to have
mistaken what is called in Scotland the conversion price for
the actual market price. Fleetwood acknowledges, upon one
occasion, that he had made this mistake. As he wrote his book,
however, for a particular purpose, he does not think proper
to make this acknowledgment till after transcribing this conversion
price fifteen times. The price is eight shillings the quarter
of wheat. This sum in 1423, the year at which he begins with
it, contained the same quantity of silver as sixteen shillings
of our present money. But in 1562, the year at which he ends
with it, it contained no more than the same nominal sum does
at present.
Secondly,
they have been misled by the slovenly manner in which some
ancient statutes of assize had been sometimes transcribed
by lazy copiers; and sometimes perhaps actually composed by
the legislature.
The
ancient statutes of assize seem to have begun always with
determining what ought to be the price of bread and ale when
the price of wheat and barley were at the lowest, and to have
proceeded gradually to determine what it ought to be, according
as the prices of those two sorts of grain should gradually
rise above this lowest price. But the transcribers of those
statutes seem frequently to have thought it sufficient to
copy the regulation as far as the three or four first and
lowest prices, saving in this manner their own labour, and
judging, I suppose, that this was enough to show what proportion
ought to be observed in all higher prices.
Thus
in the Assize of Bread and Ale, of the 51st of Henry III,
the price of bread was regulated according to the different
prices of wheat, from one shilling to twenty shillings the
quarter, of the money of those times. But in the manuscripts
from which all the different editions of the statutes, preceding
that of Mr. Ruffhead, were printed, the copiers had never
transcribed this regulation beyond the price of twelve shillings.
Several writers, therefore, being misled by this faulty transcription,
very naturally concluded that the middle price, or six shillings
the quarter, equal to about eighteen shillings of our present
money, was the ordinary or average price of wheat at that
time.
In
the Statute of Tumbrel and Pillory, enacted nearly about the
same time, the price of ale is regulated according to every
sixpence rise in the price of barley, from two shillings to
four shillings the quarter. That four shillings, however,
was not considered as the highest price to which barley might
frequently rise in those times, and that these prices were
only given as an example of the proportion which ought to
be observed in all other prices, whether higher or lower,
we may infer from the last words of the statute: et sic deinceps
crescetur vel diminuetur per sex denarios. The expression
is very slovenly, but the meaning is plain enough: "That the
price of ale is in this manner to be increased or diminished
according to every sixpence rise or fall in the price of barley."
In the composition of this statute the legislature itself
seems to have been as negligent as the copiers were in the
transcription of the others.
In
an ancient manuscript of the Regiam Majestatem, an old Scotch
law book, there is a statute of assize in which the price
of bread is regulated according to all the different prices
of wheat, from tenpence to three shillings the Scotch boll,
equal to about half an English quarter. Three shillings Scotch,
at the time when this assize is supposed to have been enacted
were equal to about nine shillings sterling of our present
money. Mr. Ruddiman seems to conclude from this, that three
shillings was the highest price to which wheat ever rose in
those times, and that tenpence, a shilling, or at most two
shillings, were the ordinary prices. Upon consulting the manuscript,
however, it appears evidently that all these prices are only
set down as examples of the proportion which ought to be observed
between the respective prices of wheat and bread. The last
words of the statute are: reliqua judicabis secundum proescripta
habendo respectum ad pretium bladi. "You shall judge of the
remaining cases according to what is above written, having
a respect to the price of corn."
Thirdly,
they seem to have been misled, too, by the very low price
at which wheat was sometimes sold in very ancient times; and
to have imagined that as its lowest price was then much lower
than in later times, its ordinary price must likewise have
been much lower. They might have found, however, that in those
ancient times its highest price was fully as much above, as
its lowest price was below anything that had even been known
in later times. Thus in 1270, Fleetwood gives us two prices
of the quarter of wheat. The one is four pounds sixteen shillings
of the money of those times, equal to fourteen pounds eight
shillings of that of the present; the other is six pounds
eight shillings, equal to nineteen pounds four shillings of
our present money. No price can be found in the end of the
fifteenth, or beginning of the sixteenth century, which approaches
to the extravagance of these. The price of corn, though at
all times liable to variation, varies most in those turbulent
and disorderly societies, in which the interruption of all
commerce and communication hinders the plenty of one part
of the country from relieving the scarcity of another. In
the disorderly state of England under the Plantagenets, who
governed it from about the middle of the twelfth till towards
the end of the fifteenth century, one district might be in
plenty, while another at no great distance, by having its
crop destroyed either by some accident of the seasons, or
by the incursion of some neighbouring baron, might be suffering
all the horrors of a famine; and yet if the lands of some
hostile lord were interposed between them, the one might not
be able to give the least assistance to the other. Under the
vigorous administration of the Tudors, who governed England
during the latter part of the fifteenth and through the whole
of the sixteenth century, no baron was powerful enough to
dare to disturb the public security.
The
reader will find at the end of this chapter all the prices
of wheat which have been collected by Fleetwood from 1202
to 1597, both inclusive, reduced to the money of the present
times, and digested according to the order of time, into seven
divisions of twelve years each. At the end of each division,
too, he will find the average price of the twelve years of
which it consists. In that long period of time, Fleetwood
has been able to collect the prices of no more than eighty
years, so that four years are wanting to make out the last
twelve years. I have added, therefore, from the accounts of
Eton college, the prices of 1598, 1599, 1600, and 1601. It
is the only addition which I have made. The reader will see
that from the beginning of the thirteenth till after the middle
of the sixteenth century the average price of each twelve
years grows gradually lower and lower; and that towards the
end of the sixteenth century it begins to rise again. The
prices, indeed, which Fleetwood has been able to collect,
seem to have been those chiefly which were remarkable for
extraordinary dearness or cheapness; and I do not pretend
that any very certain conclusion can be drawn from them. So
far, however, as they prove anything at all, they confirm
the account which I have been endeavouring to give. Fleetwood
himself, however, seems, with most other writers, to have
believed that during all this period the value of silver,
in consequence of its increasing abundance, was continually
diminishing. The prices of corn which he himself has collected
certainly do not agree with this opinion. They agree perfectly
with that of Mr. Dupre de St. Maur, and with that which I
have been endeavouring to explain. Bishop Fleetwood and Mr.
Dupre de St. Maur are the two authors who seem to have collected,
with the greatest diligence and fidelity, the prices of things
in ancient times. It is somewhat curious that, though their
opinions are so very different, their facts, so far as they
relate to the price of corn at least, should coincide so very
exactly.
It
is not, however, so much from the low price of corn as from
that of some other parts of the rude produce of land that
the most judicious writers have inferred the great value of
silver in those very ancient times. Corn, it has been said,
being a sort of manufacture, was, in those rude ages, much
dearer in proportion than the greater part of other commodities;
it is meant, I suppose, than the greater part of unmanufactured
commodities, such as cattle, poultry, game of all kinds, etc.
That in those times of poverty and barbarism these were proportionably
much cheaper than corn is undoubtedly true. But this cheapness
was not the effect of the high value of silver, but of the
low value of those commodities. It was not because silver
would in such times purchase or represent a greater quantity
of labour, but because such commodities would purchase or
represent a much smaller quantity than in times of more opulence
and improvement. Silver must certainly be cheaper in Spanish
America than in Europe; in the country where it is produced
than in the country to which it is brought, at the expense
of a long carriage both by land and by sea, of a freight and
an insurance. One-and-twenty pence halfpenny sterling, however,
we are told by Ulloa, was, not many years ago, at Buenos Ayres,
the price of an ox chosen from a herd of three or four hundred.
Sixteen shillings sterling, we are told by Mr. Byron was the
price of a good horse in the capital of Chili. In a country
naturally fertile, but of which the far greater part is altogether
uncultivated, cattle, poultry, game of all kinds, etc., as
they can be acquired with a very small quantity of labour,
so they will purchase or command but a very small quantity.
The low money price for which they may be sold is no proof
that the real value of silver is there very high, but that
the real value of those commodities is very low.
Labour,
it must always be remembered, and not any particular commodity
or set of commodities, is the real measure of the value both
of silver and of all other commodities.
But
in countries almost waste, or but thinly inhabited, cattle,
poultry, game of all kinds, etc., as they are the spontaneous
productions of nature, so she frequently produces them in
much greater quantities than the consumption of the inhabitants
requires. In such a state of things the supply commonly exceeds
the demand. In different states of society, in different stages
of improvement, therefore, such commodities will represent,
or be equivalent to, very different quantities of labour.
In
every state of society, in every stage of improvement, corn
is the production of human industry. But the average produce
of every sort of industry is always suited, more or less exactly,
to the average consumption; the average supply to the average
demand. In every different stage of improvement, besides,
the raising of equal quantities of corn in the same soil and
climate will, at an average, require nearly equal quantities
of labour; or what comes to the same thing, the price of nearly
equal quantities; the continual increase of the productive
powers of labour in an improving state of cultivation being
more or less counterbalanced by the continually increasing
price of cattle, the principal instruments of agriculture.
Upon all these accounts, therefore, we may rest assured that
equal quantities of corn will, in every state of society,
in every stage of improvement, more nearly represent, or be
equivalent to, equal quantities of labour than equal quantities
of any other part of the rude produce of land. Corn, accordingly,
it has already been observed, is, in all the different stages
of wealth and improvement, a more accurate measure of value
than any other commodity or set of commodities. In all those
different stages, therefore, we can judge better of the real
value of silver by comparing it with corn than by comparing
it with any other commodity or set of commodities.
Corn,
besides, or whatever else is the common and favourite vegetable
food of the people, constitutes, in every civilised country,
the principal part of the subsistence of the labourer. In
consequence of the extension of agriculture, the land of every
country produces a much greater quantity of vegetable than
of animal food, and the labourer everywhere lives chiefly
upon the wholesome food that is cheapest and most abundant.
Butcher's meat, except in the most thriving countries, or
where labour is most highly rewarded, makes but an insignificant
part of his subsistence; poultry makes a still smaller part
of it, and game no part of it. In France, and even in Scotland,
where labour is somewhat better rewarded than in France, the
labouring poor seldom eat butcher's meat, except upon holidays,
and other extraordinary occasions. The money price of labour,
therefore, depends much more upon the average money price
of corn, the subsistence of the labourer, than upon that of
butcher's meat, or of any other part of the rude produce of
land. The real value of gold and silver, therefore, the real
quantity of labour which they can purchase or command, depends
much more upon the quantity of corn which they can purchase
or command than upon that of butcher's meat, or any other
part of the rude produce of land.
Such
slight observations, however, upon the prices either of corn
or of other commodities, would not probably have misled so
many intelligent authors had they not been influenced, at
the same time, by the popular notion, that as the quantity
of silver naturally increases in every country with the increase
of so its value diminishes as its quantity increases. This
notion, however, seems to be altogether groundless.
The
quantity of the precious metals may increase in any country
from two different causes; either, first, from the increased
abundance of the mines which supply it; or, secondly, from
the increased wealth of the people, from the increased produce
of their annual labour. The first of these causes is no doubt
necessarily connected with the diminution of the value of
the precious metals, but the second is not.
When
more abundant mines are discovered, a greater quantity of
the precious metals is brought to market, and the quantity
of the necessaries and conveniencies of life for which they
must be exchanged being the same as before, equal quantities
of the metals must be exchanged for smaller quantities of
commodities. So far, therefore, as the increase of the quantity
of the precious metals in any country arises from the increased
abundance of the mines, it is necessarily connected with some
diminution of their value.
When,
on the contrary, the wealth of any country increases, when
the annual produce of its labour becomes gradually greater
and greater, a greater quantity of coin becomes necessary
in order to circulate a greater quantity of commodities; and
the people, as they can afford it, as they have more commodities
to give for it, will naturally purchase a greater and a greater
quantity of plate. The quantity of their coin will increase
from necessity; the quantity of their plate from vanity and
ostentation, or from the same reason that the quantity of
fine statues, pictures, and of every other luxury and curiosity,
is likely to increase among them. But as statuaries and painters
are not likely to be worse rewarded in times of wealth and
prosperity than in times of poverty and depression, so gold
and silver are not likely to be worse paid for.
The
price of gold and silver, when the accidental discovery of
more abundant mines does not keep it down, as it naturally
rises with the wealth of every country, so, whatever be the
state of the mines, it is at all times naturally higher in
a rich than in a poor country. Gold and silver, like all other
commodities, naturally seek the market where the best price
is given for them, and the best price is commonly given for
every thing in the country which can best afford it. Labour,
it must be remembered, is the ultimate price which is paid
for everything, and in countries where labour is equally well
regarded, the money price of labour will be in proportion
to that of the subsistence of the labourer. But gold and silver
will naturally exchange for a greater quantity of subsistence
in a rich than in a poor country, in a country which abounds
with subsistence than in one which is but indifferently supplied
with it. If the two countries are at a great distance, the
difference may be very great; because though the metals naturally
fly from the worse to the better market, yet it may be difficult
to transport them in such quantities as to bring their price
nearly to a level in both. If the countries are near, the
difference will be smaller, and may sometimes be scarce perceptible;
because in this case the transportation will be easy. China
is a much richer country than any part of Europe, and the
difference between the price of subsistence in China and in
Europe is very great. Rice in China is much cheaper than wheat
is anywhere in Europe. England is a much richer country than
Scotland; but the difference between the money-price of corn
in those two countries is much smaller, and is but just perceptible.
In proportion to the quantity or measure, Scotch corn generally
appears to be a good deal cheaper than English; but in proportion
to its quality, it is certainly somewhat dearer. Scotland
receives almost every year very large supplies from England,
and every commodity must commonly be somewhat dearer in the
country to which it is brought than in that from which it
comes. English corn, therefore, must be dearer in Scotland
than in England, and yet in proportion to its quality, or
to the quantity and goodness of the flour or meal which can
be made from it, it cannot commonly be sold higher there than
the Scotch corn which comes to market in competition with
it.
The
difference between the money price of labour in China and
in Europe is still greater than that between the money price
of subsistence; because the real recompense of labour is higher
in Europe than in China, the greater part of Europe being
in an improving state, while China seems to be standing still.
The money price of labour is lower in Scotland than in England
because the real recompense of labour is much lower; Scotland,
though advancing to greater wealth, advancing much more slowly
than England. The frequency of emigration from Scotland, and
the rarity of it from England, sufficiently prove that the
demand for labour is very different in the two countries.
The proportion between the real recompense of labour in different
countries, it must be remembered, is naturally regulated not
by their actual wealth or poverty, but by their advancing,
stationary, or declining condition.
Gold
and silver, as they are naturally of the greatest value among
the richest, so they are naturally of the least value among
the poorest nations. Among savages, the poorest of all nations,
they are of scarce any value.
In
great towns corn is always dearer than in remote parts of
the country. This, however, is the effect, not of the real
cheapness of silver, but of the real dearness of corn. It
does not cost less labour to bring silver to the great town
than to the remote parts of the country; but it costs a great
deal more to bring corn.
In
some very rich and commercial countries, such as Holland and
the territory of Genoa, corn is dear for the same reason that
it is dear in great towns. They do not produce enough to maintain
their inhabitants. They are rich in the industry and skill
of their artificers and manufacturers; in every sort of machinery
which can facilitate and abridge labour; in shipping, and
in all the other instruments and means of carriage and commerce:
but they are poor in corn, which, as it must be brought to
them from distant countries, must, by an addition to its price,
pay for the carriage from those countries. It does not cost
less labour to bring silver to Amsterdam than to Dantzic;
but it costs a great deal more to bring corn. The real cost
of silver must be nearly the same in both places; but that
of corn must be very different. Diminish the real opulence
either of Holland or of the territory of Genoa, while the
number of their inhabitants remains the same: diminish their
power of supplying themselves from distant countries; and
the price of corn, instead of sinking with that diminution
in the quantity of their silver, which must necessarily accompany
this declension either as its cause or as its effect, will
rise to the price of a famine. When we are in want of necessaries
we must part with all superfluities, of which the value, as
it rises in times of opulence and prosperity, so it sinks
in times of poverty and distress. It is otherwise with necessaries.
Their real price, the quantity of labour which they can purchase
or command, rises in times of poverty and distress, and sinks
in times of opulence and prosperity, which are always times
of great abundance; for they could not otherwise be times
of opulence and prosperity. Corn is a necessary, silver is
only a superfluity.
Whatever,
therefore, may have been the increase in the quantity of the
precious metals, which, during the period between the middle
of the fourteenth and that of the sixteenth century, arose
from the increase of wealth and improvement, it could have
no tendency to diminish their value either in Great Britain
or in any other part of Europe. If those who have collected
the prices of things in ancient times, therefore, had, during
this period, no reason to infer the diminution of the value
of silver, from any observations which they had made upon
the prices either of corn or of other commodities, they had
still less reason to infer it from any supposed increase of
wealth and improvement.
SECOND
PERIOD
But
how various soever may have been the opinions of the learned
concerning the progress of the value of silver during this
first period, they are unanimous concerning it during the
second.
From
about 1570 to about 1640, during a period of about seventy
years, the variation in the proportion between the value of
silver and that of corn held a quite opposite course. Silver
sunk in its real value, or would exchange for a smaller quantity
of labour than before; and corn rose in its nominal price,
and instead of being commonly sold for about two ounces of
silver the quarter, or about ten shillings of our present
money, came to be sold for six and eight ounces of silver
the quarter, or about thirty and forty shillings of our present
money.
The
discovery of the abundant mines of America seems to have been
the sole cause of this diminution in the value of silver in
proportion to that of corn. It is accounted for accordingly
in the same manner by everybody; and there never has been
any dispute either about the fact or about the cause of it.
The greater part of Europe was, during this period, advancing
in industry and improvement, and the demand for silver must
consequently have been increasing. But the increase of the
supply had, it seems, so far exceeded that of the demand,
that the value of that metal sunk considerably. The discovery
of the mines of America, it is to be observed, does not seem
to have had any very sensible effect upon the prices of things
in England till after 1570; though even the mines of Potosi
had been discovered more than twenty years before.
From
1595 to 1620, both inclusive, the average price of the quarter
of nine bushels of the best wheat at Windsor market appears,
from the accounts of Eton College, to have been L2 1s. 6 3/4d.
From which sum, neglecting the fraction, and deducting a ninth,
or 4s. 7 1\3d., the price of the quarter of eight bushels
comes out to have been L1 16s. 10 2/3d. And from this sum,
neglecting likewise the fraction, and deducting a ninth, or
4s. 1d., for the difference between the price of the best
wheat and that of the middle wheat, the price of the middle
wheat comes out to have been about L1 12s. 9d., or about six
ounces and one-third of an ounce of silver.
From
1621 to 1636, both inclusive, the average price of the same
measure of the best wheat at the same market appears, from
the same accounts, to have been L2 10s.; from which making
the like deductions as in the foregoing case, the average
price of the quarter of eight bushels of middle wheat comes
out to have been L1 19s. 6d., or about seven ounces and two-thirds
of an ounce of silver.
THIRD
PERIOD
Between
1630 and 1640, or about 1636, the effect of the discovery
of the mines of America in reducing the value of silver appears
to have been completed, and the value of that metal seems
never to have sunk lower in proportion to that of corn than
it was about that time. It seems to have risen somewhat in
the course of the present century, and it had probably begun
to do so even some time before the end of the last.
From
1637 to 1700, both inclusive, being the sixty-four last years
of the last century, the average price of the quarter of nine
bushels of the best wheat at Windsor market appears, from
the same accounts, to have been L2 11s. O 1\3d., which is
only 1s O 1\3d. dearer than it had been during the sixteen
years before. But in the course of these sixty-four years
there happened two events which must have produced a much
greater scarcity of corn than what the course of the seasons
would otherwise have occasioned, and which, therefore, without
supposing any further reduction in the value of silver, will
much more than account for this very small enhancement of
price.
The
first of these events was the civil war, which, by discouraging
tillage and interrupting commerce, must have raised the price
of corn much above what the course of the seasons would otherwise
have occasioned. It must have had this effect more or less
at all the different markets in the kingdom, but particularly
at those in the neighbourhood of London, which require to
be supplied from the greatest distance. In 1648, accordingly,
the price of the best wheat at Windsor market appears, from
the same accounts, to have been L4 5s., and in 1649 to have
been L4 the quarter of nine bushels. The excess of those two
years above L2 10s. (the average price of the sixteen years
preceding 1637) is L3 5s.; which divided among the sixty-four
last years of the last century will alone very nearly account
for that small enhancement of price which seems to have taken
place in them. These, however, though the highest, are by
no means the only high prices which seem to have been occasioned
by the civil wars.
The
second event was the bounty upon the exportation of corn granted
in 1688. The bounty, it has been thought by many people, by
encouraging tillage, may, in a long course of years, have
occasioned a greater abundance, and consequently a greater
cheapness of corn in the home-market than what would otherwise
have taken place there. How far the bounty could produce this
effect at any time, I shall examine hereafter; I shall only
observe at present that, between 1688 and 1700, it had not
time to produce any such effect. During this short period
its only effect must have been, by encouraging the exportation
of the surplus produce of every year, and thereby hindering
the abundance of one year from compensating the scarcity of
another, to raise the price in the home-market. The scarcity
which prevailed in England from 1693 to 1699, both inclusive,
though no doubt principally owing to the badness of the seasons,
and, therefore, extending through a considerable part of Europe,
must have been somewhat enhanced by the bounty. In 1699, accordingly,
the further exportation of corn was prohibited for nine months.
There
was a third event which occurred in the course of the same
period, and which, though it could not occasion any scarcity
of corn, nor, perhaps, any augmentation in the real quantity
of silver which was usually paid for it, must necessarily
have occasioned some augmentation in the nominal sum. This
event was the great debasement of the silver coin, by clipping
and wearing. This evil had begun in the reign of Charles II
and had gone on continually increasing till 1695; at which
time, as we may learn from Mr. Lowndes, the current silver
coin was, at an average, near five-and-twenty per cent below
its standard value. But the nominal sum which constitutes
the market price of every commodity is necessarily regulated,
not so much by the quantity of silver, which, according to
the standard, ought to be contained in it, as by that which,
it is found by experience, actually is contained in it. This
nominal sum, therefore, is necessarily higher when the coin
is much debased by clipping and wearing than when near to
its standard value.
In
the course of the present century, the silver coin has not
at any time been more below its standard weight than it is
at present. But though very much defaced, its value has been
kept up by that of the gold coin for which it is exchanged.
For though before the late recoinage, the gold coin was a
good deal defaced too, it was less so than the silver. In
1695, on the contrary, the value of the silver coin was not
kept up by the gold coin; a guinea then commonly exchanging
for thirty shillings of the worn and clipt silver. Before
the late recoinage of the gold, the price of silver bullion
was seldom higher than five shillings and sevenpence an ounce,
which is but fivepence above the mint price. But in 1695,
the common price of silver bullion was six shillings and fivepence
an ounce, which is fifteenpence above the mint price. Even
before the late recoinage of the gold, therefore, the coin,
gold and silver together, when compared with silver bullion,
was not supposed to be more than eight per cent below its
standard value. In 1695, on the contrary, it had been supposed
to be near five-and-twenty per cent below that value. But
in the beginning of the present century, that is, immediately
after the great recoinage in King William's time. the greater
part of the current silver coin must have been still nearer
to its standard weight than it is at present. In the course
of the present century, too, there has been no great public
calamity, such as the civil war, which could either discourage
tillage, or interrupt the interior commerce of the country.
And though the bounty, which has taken place through the greater
part of this century, must always raise the price of corn
somewhat higher than it otherwise would be in the actual state
of tillage; yet as, in the course of this century, the bounty
has had full time to produce all the good effects commonly
imputed to it, to encourage tillage, and thereby to increase
the quantity of corn in the home market, it may, upon the
principles of a system which I shall explain and examine hereafter,
be supposed to have done something to lower the price of that
commodity the one way, as well as to raise it the other. It
is by many people supposed to have done more. In the sixty-four
first years of the present century accordingly the average
price of the quarter of nine bushels of the best wheat at
Windsor market appears, by the accounts of Eton College, to
have been L2 os. 6 1/2d., which is about ten shillings and
sixpence, or more than five-and-twenty per cent, cheaper than
it had been during the sixty-four last years of the last century;
and about 9s. 6d. cheaper than it had been during the sixteen
years preceding 1636, when the discovery of the abundant mines
of America may be supposed to have produced its full effect;
and about one shilling cheaper than it had been in the twenty-six
years preceding 1620, before that discovery can well be supposed
to have produced its full effect. According to this account,
the average price of middle wheat, during these sixty-four
first years of the present century, comes out to have been
about thirty-two shillings the quarter of eight bushels.
The
value of silver, therefore, seems to have risen somewhat in
proportion to that of corn during the course of the present
century, and it had probably begun to do so even some time
before the end of the last.
In
1687, the price of the quarter of nine bushels of the best
wheat at Windsor market was L1 5s. 2d. the lowest price at
which it had ever been from 1595.
In
1688, Mr. Gregory King, a man famous for his knowledge in
matters of this kind, estimated the average price of wheat
in years of moderate plenty to be to the grower 3s. 6d. the
bushel, or eight-and-twenty shillings the quarter. The grower's
price I understand to be the same with what is sometimes called
the contract price, or the price at which a farmer contracts
for a certain number of years to deliver a certain quantity
of corn to a dealer. As a contract of this kind saves the
farmer the expense and trouble of marketing, the contract
price is generally lower than what is supposed to be the average
market price. Mr. King had judged eight-and-twenty shillings
the quarter to be at that time the ordinary contract price
in years of moderate plenty. Before the scarcity occasioned
by the late extraordinary course of bad seasons, it was, I
have been assured, the ordinary contract price in all common
years.
In
1688 was granted the Parliamentary bounty upon the exportation
of corn. The country gentlemen, who then composed a still
greater proportion of the legislature than they do at present,
had felt that the money price of corn was falling. The bounty
was an expedient to raise it artificially to the high price
at which it had frequently been sold in the times of Charles
I and III. It was to take place, therefore, till wheat was
so high as forty-eight shillings the quarter, that is, twenty
shillings, or five-sevenths dearer than Mr. King had in that
very year estimated the grower's price to be in times of moderate
plenty. If his calculations deserve any part of the reputation
which they have obtained very universally, eight-and-forty
shillings the quarter was a price which, without some such
expedient as the bounty, could not at that time be expected,
except in years of extraordinary scarcity. But the government
of King William was not then fully settled. It was in no condition
to refuse anything to the country gentlemen, from whom it
was at that very time soliciting the first establishment of
the annual land-tax.
The
value of silver, therefore, in proportion to that of corn,
had probably risen somewhat before the end of the last century;
and it seems to have continued to do so during the course
of the greater part of the present; though the necessary operation
of the bounty must have hindered that rise from being so sensible
as it otherwise would have been in the actual state of tillage.
In
plentiful years the bounty, by occasioning an extraordinary
exportation, necessarily raises the price of corn above what
it otherwise would be in those years. To encourage tillage,
by keeping up the price of corn even in the most plentiful
years, was the avowed end of the institution.
In
years of great scarcity, indeed, the bounty has generally
been suspended. It must, however, have had some effect even
upon the prices of many of those years. By the extraordinary
exportation which it occasions in years of plenty, it must
frequently hinder the plenty of one year from compensating
the scarcity of another.
Both
in years of plenty and in years of scarcity, therefore, the
bounty raises the price of corn above what it naturally would
be in the actual state of tillage. If, during the sixty-four
first years of the present century, therefore, the average
price has been lower than during the sixty-four last years
of the last century, it must, in the same state of tillage,
have been much more so, had it not been for this operation
of the bounty.
But
without the bounty, it may be said, the state of tillage would
not have been the same. What may have been the effects of
this institution upon the agriculture of the country, I shall
endeavour to explain hereafter, when I come to treat particularly
of bounties. I shall only observe at present that this rise
in the value of silver, in proportion to that of corn, has
not been peculiar to England. It has been observed to have
taken place in France, during the same period, and nearly
in the same proportion too, by three very faithful, diligent,
and laborious collectors of the prices of corn, Mr. Dupre
de St. Maur, Mr. Messance, and the author of the Essay on
the police of grain. But in France, till 1764, the exportation
of grain was by law prohibited; and it is somewhat difficult
to suppose that nearly the same diminution of price which
took place in one country, notwithstanding this prohibition,
should in another be owing to the extraordinary encouragement
given to exportation.
It
would be more proper, perhaps, to consider this variation
in the average money price of corn as the effect rather of
some gradual rise in the real value of silver in the European
market than of any fall in the real average value of corn.
Corn, it has already been observed, is at distant periods
of time a more accurate measure of value than either silver,
or perhaps any other commodity. When, after the discovery
of the abundant mines of America, corn rose to three and four
times its former money price, this change was universally
ascribed, not to any rise in the real value of corn, but to
a fall in the real value of silver. If during the sixty-four
first years of the present century, therefore, the average
money price of corn has fallen somewhat below what it had
been during the greater part of the last century, we should
in the same manner impute this change, not to any fall in
the real value of corn, but to some rise in the real value
of silver in the European market.
The
high price of corn during these ten or twelve years past,
indeed, has occasioned a suspicion that the real value of
silver still continues to fall in the European market. This
high price of corn, however, seems evidently to have been
the effect of the extraordinary unfavourableness of the seasons,
and ought therefore to be regarded, not as a permanent, but
as a transitory and occasional event. The seasons for these
ten or twelve years past have been unfavourable through the
greater part of Europe; and the disorders of Poland have very
much increased the scarcity in all those countries which,
in dear years, used to be supplied from that market. So long
a course of bad seasons, though not a very common event, is
by no means a singular one; and whoever has inquired much
into the history of the prices of corn in former times will
be at no loss to recollect several other examples of the same
kind. Ten years of extraordinary scarcity, besides, are not
more wonderful than ten years of extraordinary plenty. The
low price of corn from 1741 to 1750, both inclusive, may very
well be set in opposition to its high price during these last
eight or ten years. From 1741 to 1750, the average price of
the quarter of nine bushels of the best wheat at Windsor market,
it appears from the accounts of Eton College, was only L1
13s. 9 1/2d., which is nearly 6s. 3d. below the average price
of the sixty-four first years of the present century. The
average price of the quarter of eight bushels of middle wheat
comes out, according to this account, to have been, during
these ten years, only 51 6s. 8d.
Between
1741 and 1750, however, the bounty must have hindered the
price of corn from falling so low in the home market as it
naturally would have done. During these ten years the quantity
of all sorts of grain exported, it appears from the custom-house
books, amounted to no less than eight millions twenty-nine
thousand one hundred and fifty-six quarters one bushel. The
bounty paid for this amounted to L1,514,962 17s. 4 1/2d. In
1749 accordingly, Mr. Pelham, at that time Prime Minister,
observed to the House of Commons that for the three years
preceding a very extraordinary sum had been paid as bounty
for the exportation of corn. He had good reason to make this
observation, and in the following year he might have had still
better. In that single year the bounty paid amounted to no
less than L324,176 10s. 6d. It is unnecessary to observe how
much this forced exportation must have raised the price of
corn above what it otherwise would have been in the home market.
At
the end of the accounts annexed to this chapter the reader
will find the particular account of those ten years separated
from the rest. He will find there, too, the particular account
of the preceding ten years, of which the average is likewise
below, though not so much below, the general average of the
sixty-four first years of the century. The year 1740, however,
was a year of extraordinary scarcity. These twenty years preceding
1750 may very well be set in opposition to the twenty preceding
1770. As the former were a good deal below the general average
of the century, notwithstanding the intervention of one or
two dear years; so the latter have been a good deal above
it, notwithstanding the intervention of one or two cheap ones,
of 1759, for example. If the former have not been as much
below the general average as the latter have been above it,
we ought probably to impute it to the bounty. The change has
evidently been too sudden to be ascribed to any change in
the value of silver, which is always slow and gradual. The
suddenness of the effect can be accounted for only by a cause
which can operate suddenly, the accidental variation of the
seasons.
The
money price of labour in Great Britain has, indeed, risen
during the course of the present century. This, however, seems
to be the effect, not so much of any diminution in the value
of silver in the European market, as of an increase in the
demand for labour in Great Britain, arising from the great,
and almost universal prosperity of the country. In France,
a country not altogether so prosperous, the money price of
labour has, since the middle of the last century, been observed
to sink gradually with the average money price of corn. Both
in the last century and in the present the day-wages of common
labour are there said to have been pretty uniformly about
the twentieth part of the average price of the septier of
wheat, a measure which contains a little more than four Winchester
bushels. In Great Britain the real recompense of labour, it
has already been shown, the real quantities of the necessaries
and conveniencies of life which are given to the labourer,
has increased considerably during the course of the present
century. The rise in its money price seems to have been the
effect, not of any diminution of the value of silver in the
general market of Europe, but of a rise in the real price
of labour in the particular market of Great Britain, owing
to the peculiarly happy circumstances of the country.
For
some time after the first discovery of America, silver would
continue to sell at its former, or not much below its former
price. The profits of mining would for some time be very great,
and much above their natural rate. Those who imported that
metal into Europe, however, would soon find that the whole
annual importation could not be disposed of at this high price.
Silver would gradually exchange for a smaller and a smaller
quantity of goods. Its price would sink gradually lower and
lower till it fell to its natural price, or to what was just
sufficient to pay, according to their natural rates, the wages
of the labour, the profits of the stock, and the rent of the
land, which must be paid in order to bring it from the mine
to the market. In the greater part of the silver mines of
Peru, the tax of the King of Spain, amounting to a tenth of
the gross produce, eats up, it has already been observed,
the whole rent of the land. This tax was originally a half;
it soon afterwards fell to a third, then to a fifth, and at
last to a tenth, at which rate it still continues. In the
greater part of the silver mines of Peru this, it seems, is
all that remains after replacing the stock of the undertaker
of the work, together with its ordinary profits; and it seems
to be universally acknowledged that these profits, which were
once very high, are now as low as they can well be, consistently
with carrying on their works.
The
tax of the King of Spain was reduced to a fifth part of the
registered silver in 1504, one-and-forty years before 1545,
the date of the discovery of the mines of Potosi. In the course
of ninety years, or before 1636, these mines, the most fertile
in all America, had time sufficient to produce their full
effect, or to reduce the value of silver in the European market
as low as it could well fall, while it continued to pay this
tax to the King of Spain. Ninety years is time sufficient
to reduce any commodity, of which there is no monopoly, to
its natural price, or to the lowest price at which, while
it pays a particular tax, it can continue to be sold for any
considerable time together.
The
price of silver in the European market might perhaps have
fallen still lower, and it might have become necessary either
to reduce the tax upon it, not only to one tenth, as in 1736,
but to one twentieth, in the same manner as that upon gold,
or to give up working the greater part of the American mines
which are now wrought. The gradual increase of the demand
for silver, or the gradual enlargement of the market for the
produce of the silver mines of America, is probably the cause
which has prevented this from happening, and which has not
only kept up the value of silver in the European market, but
has perhaps even raised it somewhat higher than it was about
the middle of the last century.
Since
the first discovery of America, the market for the produce
of its silver mines has been growing gradually more and more
extensive.
First,
the market of Europe has become gradually more and more extensive.
Since the discovery of America, the greater part of Europe
has been much improved. England, Holland, France, and Germany;
even Sweden, Denmark, and Russia, have all advanced considerably
both in agriculture and in manufactures. Italy seems not to
have gone backwards. The fall of Italy preceded the conquest
of Peru. Since that time it seems rather to have recovered
a little. Spain and Portugal, indeed, are supposed to have
gone backwards. Portugal, however, is but a very small part
of Europe, and the declension of Spain is not, perhaps, so
great as is commonly imagined. In the beginning of the sixteenth
century, Spain was a very poor country, even in comparison
with France, which has been so much improved since that time.
It was the well known remark of the Emperor Charles V, who
had travelled so frequently through both countries, that everything
abounded in France, but that everything was wanting in Spain.
The increasing produce of the agriculture and manufactures
of Europe must necessarily have required a gradual increase
in the quantity of silver coin to circulate it; and the increasing
number of wealthy individuals must have required the like
increase in the quantity of their plate and other ornaments
of silver.
Secondly,
America is itself a new market for the produce of its own
silver mines; and as its advances in agriculture, industry,
and population are much more rapid than those of the most
thriving countries in Europe, its demand must increase much
more rapidly. The English colonies are altogether a new market,
which, partly for coin and partly for plate, requires a continually
augmenting supply of silver through a great continent where
there never was any demand before. The greater part, too,
of the Spanish and Portuguese colonies are altogether new
markets. New Granada, the Yucatan, Paraguay, and the Brazils
were, before discovered by the Europeans, inhabited by savage
nations who had neither arts nor agriculture. A considerable
degree of both has now been introduced into all of them. Even
Mexico and Peru, though they cannot be considered as altogether
new markets, are certainly much more extensive ones than they
ever were before. After all the wonderful tales which have
been published concerning the splendid state of those countries
in ancient times, whoever reads, with any degree of sober
judgment, the history of their first discovery and conquest,
will evidently discern that, in arts, agriculture, and commerce,
their inhabitants were much more ignorant than the Tartars
of the Ukraine are at present. Even the Peruvians, the more
civilised nation of the two, though they made use of gold
and silver as ornaments, had no coined money of any kind.
Their whole commerce was carried on by barter, and there was
accordingly scarce any division of labour among them. Those
who cultivated the ground were obliged to build their own
houses, to make their own household furniture, their own clothes,
shoes, and instruments of agriculture. The few artificers
among them are said to have been all maintained by the sovereign,
the nobles, and the priests, and were probably their servants
or slaves. All the ancient arts of Mexico and Peru have never
furnished one single manufacture to Europe. The Spanish armies,
though they scarce ever exceeded five hundred men, and frequently
did not amount to half that number, found almost everywhere
great difficulty in procuring subsistence. The famines which
they are said to have occasioned almost wherever they went,
in countries, too, which at the same time are represented
as very populous and well cultivated, sufficiently demonstrate
that the story of this populousness and high cultivation is
in a great measure fabulous. The Spanish colonies are under
a government in many respects less favourable to agriculture,
improvement, and population than that of the English colonies.
They seem, however, to be advancing in all these much more
rapidly than any country in Europe. In a fertile soil and
happy climate, the great abundance and cheapness of land,
a circumstance common to all new colonies, is, it seems, so
great an advantage as to compensate many defects in civil
government. Frezier, who visited Peru in 1713, represents
Lima as containing between twenty-five and twenty-eight thousand
inhabitants. Ulloa, who resided in the same country between
1740 and 1746, represents it as containing more than fifty
thousand. The difference in their accounts of the populousness
of several other principal towns in Chili and Peru is nearly
the same; and as there seems to be no reason to doubt of the
good information of either, it marks an increase which is
scarce inferior to that of the English colonies. America,
therefore, is a new market for the produce of its own silver
mines, of which the demand must increase much more rapidly
than that of the most thriving country in Europe.
Thirdly,
the East Indies is another market for the produce of the silver
mines of America, and a market which, from the time of the
first discovery of those mines, has been continually taking
off a greater and a greater quantity of silver. Since that
time, the direct trade between America and the East Indies,
which is carried on by means of the Acapulco ships, has been
continually augmenting, and the indirect intercourse by the
way of Europe has been augmenting in a still greater proportion.
During the sixteenth century, the Portuguese were the only
European nation who carried on any regular trade to the East
Indies. In the last years of that century the Dutch begun
to encroach upon this monopoly, and in a few years expelled
them from their principal settlements in India. During the
greater part of the last century those two nations divided
the most considerable part of the East India trade between
them; the trade of the Dutch continually augmenting in a still
greater proportion than that of the Portuguese declined. The
English and French carried on some trade with India in the
last century, but it has been greatly augmented in the course
of the present. The East India trade of the Swedes and Danes
began in the course of the present century. Even the Muscovites
now trade regularly with China by a sort of caravans which
go overland through Siberia and Tartary to Pekin. The East
India trade of all these nations, if we except that of the
French, which the last war had well nigh annihilated, had
been almost continually augmenting. The increasing consumption
of East India goods in Europe is, it seems, so great as to
afford a gradual increase of employment to them all. Tea,
for example, was a drug very little used in Europe before
the middle of the last century. At present the value of the
tea annually imported by the English East India Company, for
the use of their own countrymen, amounts to more than a million
and a half a year; and even this is not enough; a great deal
more being constantly smuggled into the country from the ports
of Holland, from Gottenburgh in Sweden, and from the coast
of France too, as long as the French East India Company was
in prosperity. The consumption of the porcelain of China,
of the spiceries of the Moluccas, of the piece goods of Bengal,
and of innumerable other articles, has increased very nearly
in a like proportion. The tonnage accordingly of all the European
shipping employed in the East India trade, at any one time
during the last century, was not, perhaps, much greater than
that of the English East India Company before the late reduction
of their shipping.
But
in the East Indies, particularly in China and Indostan, the
value of the precious metals, when the Europeans first began
to trade to those countries, was much higher than in Europe;
and it still continues to be so. In rice countries, which
generally yield two, sometimes three crops in the year, each
of them more plentiful than any common crop of corn, the abundance
of food must be much greater than in any corn country of equal
extent. Such countries are accordingly much more populous.
In them, too, the rich, having a greater superabundance of
food to dispose of beyond what they themselves can consume,
have the means of purchasing a much greater quantity of the
labour of other people. The retinue of a grandee in China
or Indostan accordingly is, by all accounts, much more numerous
and splendid than that of the richest subjects in Europe.
The same superabundance of food, of which they have the disposal,
enables them to give a greater quantity of it for all those
singular and rare productions which nature furnishes but in
very small quantities; such as the precious metals and the
precious stones, the great objects of the competition of the
rich. Though the mines, therefore, which supplied the Indian
market had been as abundant as those which supplied the European,
such commodities would naturally exchange for a greater quantity
of food in India than in Europe. But the mines which supplied
the Indian market with the precious metals seem to have been
a good deal less abundant, and those which supplied it with
the precious stones a good deal more so, than the mines which
supplied the European. The precious metals, therefore, would
naturally exchange in India for somewhat a greater quantity
of the precious stones, and for a much greater quantity of
food than in Europe. The money price of diamonds, the greatest
of all superfluities, would be somewhat lower, and that of
food, the first of all necessaries, a great deal lower in
the one country than in the other. But the real price of labour,
the real quantity of the necessaries of life which is given
to the labourer, it has already been observed, is lower both
in China and Indostan, the two great markets of India, than
it is through the greater part of Europe. The wages of the
labourer will there purchase a smaller quantity of food; and
as the money price of food is much lower in India than in
Europe, the money price of labour is there lower upon a double
account; upon account both of the small quantity of food which
it will purchase, and of the low price of that food. But in
countries of equal art and industry, the money price of the
greater part of manufactures will be in proportion to the
money price of labour; and in manufacturing art and industry,
China and Indostan, though inferior, seem not to be much inferior
to any part of Europe. The money price of the greater part
of manufactures, therefore, will naturally be much lower in
those great empires than it is anywhere in Europe. Through
the greater part of Europe, too, the expense of land-carriage
increases very much both the real and nominal price of most
manufactures. It costs more labour, and therefore more money,
to bring first the materials, and afterwards the complete
manufacture to market. In China and Indostan the extent and
variety of inland navigation save the greater part of this
labour, and consequently of this money, and thereby reduce
still lower both the real and the nominal price of the greater
part of their manufactures. Upon all those accounts the precious
metals axe a commodity which it always has been, and still
continues to be, extremely advantageous to carry from Europe
to India. There is scarce any commodity which brings a better
price there; or which, in proportion to the quantity of labour
and commodities which it costs in Europe, will purchase or
command a greater quantity of labour and commodities in India.
It is more advantageous, too, to carry silver thither than
gold; because in China, and the greater part of the other
markets of India, the proportion between fine silver and fine
gold is but as ten, or at most as twelve, to one; whereas
in Europe it is as fourteen or fifteen to one. In China, and
the greater part of the other markets of India, ten, or at
most twelve, ounces of silver will purchase an ounce of gold;
in Europe it requires from fourteen to fifteen ounces. In
the cargoes, therefore, of the greater part of European ships
which sail to India, silver has generally been one of the
most valuable articles. It is the most valuable article in
the Acapulco ships which sail to Manilla. The silver of the
new continent seems in this manner to be one of the principal
commodities by which the commerce between the two extremities
of the old one is carried on, and it is by means of it, in
a great measure, that those distant parts of the world are
connected with one another.
In
order to supply so very widely extended a market, the quantity
of silver annually brought from the mines must not only be
sufficient to support that continual increase both of coin
and of plate which is required in all thriving countries;
but to repair that continual waste and consumption of silver
which takes place in all countries where that metal is used.
The
continual consumption of the precious metals in coin by wearing,
and in plate both by wearing and cleaning, is very sensible,
and in commodities of which the use is so very widely extended,
would alone require a very great annual supply. The consumption
of those metals in some particular manufactures, though it
may not perhaps be greater upon the whole than this gradual
consumption, is, however, much more sensible, as it is much
more rapid. In the manufactures of Birmingham alone the quantity
of gold and silver annually employed in gilding and plating,
and thereby disqualified from ever afterwards appearing in
the shape of those metals, is said to amount to more than
fifty thousand pounds sterling. We may from thence form some
notion how great must be the annual consumption in all the
different parts of the world either in manufactures of the
same kind with those of Birmingham, or in laces, embroideries,
gold and silver stuffs, the gilding of books, furniture, etc.
A considerable quantity, too, must be annually lost in transporting
those metals from one place to another both by sea and by
land. In the greater part of the governments of Asia, besides,
the almost universal custom of concealing treasures in the
bowels of the earth, of which the knowledge frequently dies
with the person who makes the concealment, must occasion the
loss of a still greater quantity.
The
quantity of gold and silver imported at both Cadiz and Lisbon
(including not only what comes under register, but what may
be supposed to be smuggled) amounts, according to the best
accounts, to about six millions sterling a year.
According
to Mr. Meggens the annual importation of the precious metals
into Spain, at an average of six years, viz., from 1748 to
1753, both inclusive; and into Portugal, at an average of
seven years, viz., from 1747 to 1753, both inclusive, amounted
in silver to 1,101,107 pounds weight; and in gold to 29,940
pounds weight. The silver, at sixty-two shillings the pound
Troy, amounts to L3,413,431 10s. sterling. The gold, at forty-four
guineas and a half the pound Troy, amounts to L2,333,446 14s.
sterling. Both together amount to L5,746,878 4s. sterling.
The account of what was imported under register he assures
us is exact. He gives us the detail of the particular places
from which the gold and silver were brought, and of the particular
quantity of each metal, which, according to the register,
each of them afforded. He makes an allowance, too, for the
quantity of each metal which he supposes may have been smuggled.
The great experience of this judicious merchant renders his
opinion of considerable weight.
According
to the eloquent and, sometimes, well-informed author of the
Philosophical and Political History of the Establishment of
the Europeans in the two Indies, the annual importation of
registered gold and silver into Spain, at an average of eleven
years, viz., from 1754 to 1764, both inclusive, amounted to
13,984,185 3/4 piastres of ten reals. On account of what may
have been smuggled, however, the whole annual importation,
he supposes, may have amounted to seventeen millions of piastres,
which, at 4s. 6d. the piastre, is equal to L3,825,000 sterling.
He gives the detail, too, of the particular places from which
the gold and silver were brought, and of the particular quantities
of each metal which, according to the register, each of them
afforded. He informs us, too, that if we were to judge of
the quantity of gold annually imported from the Brazils into
Lisbon by the amount of the tax paid to the King of Portugal,
which it seems is one-fifth of the standard metal, we might
value it at eighteen millions of cruzadoes, or forty-five
millions of French livres, equal to about two millions sterling.
On account of what may have been smuggled, however, we may
safely, he says, add to the sum an eighth more, or L250,000
sterling, so that the whole will amount to L2,250,000 sterling.
According to this account, therefore, the whole annual importation
of the precious metals into both Spain and Portugal amounts
to about L6,075,000 sterling.
Several
other very well authenticated, though manuscript, accounts,
I have been assured, agree in making this whole annual importation
amount at an average to about six millions sterling; sometimes
a little more, sometimes a little less.
The
annual importation of the precious metals into Cadiz and Lisbon,
indeed, is not equal to the whole annual produce of the mines
of America. Some part is sent annually by the Acapulco ships
to Manilla; some part is employed in the contraband trade
which the Spanish colonies carry on with those of other European
nations; and some part, no doubt remains in the country. The
mines of America, besides, are by no means the only gold and
silver mines in the world. They are, however, by far the most
abundant. The produce of all the other mines which are known
is insignificant, it is acknowledged, in comparison with theirs;
and the far greater part of their produce, it is likewise
acknowledged, is annually imported into Cadiz and Lisbon.
But the consumption of Birmingham alone, at the rate of fifty
thousand pounds a year, is equal to the hundred-and-twentieth
part of this annual importation at the rate of six millions
a year. The whole annual consumption of gold and silver, therefore,
in all the different countries of the world where those metals
are used, may perhaps be nearly equal to the whole annual
produce. The remainder may be no more than sufficient to supply
the increasing demand of all thriving countries. It may even
have fallen so far short of time demand as somewhat to raise
the price of those metals in the European market.
The
quantity of brass and iron annually brought from the mine
to the market is out of all proportion greater than that of
gold and silver. We do not, however, upon this account, imagine
that those coarse metals are likely to multiply beyond the
demand, or to become gradually cheaper and cheaper. Why should
we imagine that the precious metals are likely to do so? The
coarse metals, indeed, though harder, are put to much harder
uses, and, as they are of less value, less care is employed
in their preservation. The precious metals, however, are not
necessarily immortal any more than they, but are liable, too,
to be lost, wasted, and consumed in a great variety of ways.
The
price of all metals, though liable to slow and gradual variations,
varies less from year to year than that of almost any other
part of the rude produce of land; and the price of the precious
metals is even less liable to sudden variations than that
of the coarse ones. The durableness of metals is the foundation
of this extraordinary steadiness of price. The corn which
was brought to market last year will be all or almost all
consumed long before the end of this year. But some part of
the iron which was brought from the mine two or three hundred
years ago may be still in use, and perhaps some part of the
gold which was brought from it two or three thousand years
ago. The different masses of corn which in different years
must supply the consumption of the world will always be nearly
in proportion to the respective produce of those different
years. But the proportion between the different masses of
iron which may be in use in two different years will be very
little affected by any accidental difference in the produce
of the iron mines of those two years; and the proportion between
the masses of gold will be still less affected by any such
difference in the produce of the gold mines. Though the produce
of the greater part of metallic mines, therefore, varies,
perhaps, still more from year to year than that of the greater
part of corn fields, those variations have not the same effect
upon the price of the one species of commodities as upon that
of the other.
VARIATIONS
IN THE PROPORTION
BETWEEN THE RESPECTIVE VALUES
OF GOLD AND SILVER
Before
the discovery of the mines of America, the value of fine gold
to fine silver was regulated in the different mints of Europe
between the proportions of one to ten and one to twelve; that
is, an ounce of fine gold was supposed to be worth from ten
to twelve ounces of fine silver. About the middle of the last
century it came to be regulated, between the proportions of
one to fourteen and one to fifteen; that is, an ounce of fine
gold came to be supposed to be worth between fourteen and
fifteen ounces of fine silver. Gold rose in its nominal value,
or in the quantity of silver which was given for it. Both
metals sunk in their real value, or in the quantity of labour
which they could purchase; but silver sunk more than gold.
Though both the gold and silver mines of America exceeded
in fertility all those which had ever been known before, the
fertility of the silver mines had, it seems, been proportionably
still greater than that of the gold ones.
The
great quantities of silver carried annually from Europe to
India have, in some of the English settlements, gradually
reduced the value of that metal in proportion to gold. In
the mint of Calcutta an ounce of fine gold is supposed to
be worth fifteen ounces of fine silver, in the same manner
as in Europe. It is in the mint perhaps rated too high for
the value which it bears in the market of Bengal. In China,
the proportion of gold to silver still continues as one to
ten, or one to twelve. In Japan it is said to be as one to
eight.
The
proportion between the quantities of gold and silver annually
imported into Europe, according to Mr. Meggens's account,
is as one to twenty-two nearly; that is, for one ounce of
gold there are imported a little more than twenty-two ounces
of silver. The great quantity of silver sent annually to the
East Indies reduces, he supposes, the quantities of those
metals which remain in Europe to the proportion of one to
fourteen or fifteen, the proportion of their values. The proportion
between their values, he seems to think, must necessarily
be the same as that between their quantities, and would therefore
be as one to twenty-two, were it not for this greater exportation
of silver.
But
the ordinary proportion between the respective values of two
commodities is not necessarily the same as that between the
quantities of them which are commonly in the market. The price
of an ox, reckoned at ten guineas, is about threescore times
the price of a lamb, reckoned at 3s. 6d. It would be absurd,
however, to infer from thence that there are commonly in the
market threescore lambs for one ox: and it would be just as
absurd to infer, because an ounce of gold will commonly purchase
from fourteen to fifteen ounces of silver, that there are
commonly in the market only fourteen or fifteen ounces of
silver for one ounce of gold.
The
quantity of silver commonly in the market, it is probable
is much greater in proportion to that of gold than the value
of a certain quantity of gold is to that of an equal quantity
of silver. The whole quantity of a cheap commodity brought
to market is commonly not only greater, but of greater value,
than the whole quantity of a dear one. The whole quantity
of bread annually brought to market is not only greater, but
of greater value than the whole quantity of butcher's meat;
the whole quantity of butcher's meat, than the whole quantity
of poultry; and the whole quantity of wild fowl. There are
so many more purchasers for the cheap than for the dear commodity
that not only a greater quantity of it, but a greater value,
can commonly be disposed of. The whole quantity, therefore,
of the cheap commodity must commonly be greater in proportion
to the whole quantity of the dear one than the value of a
certain quantity of the dear one is to the value of an equal
quantity of the cheap one. When we compare the precious metals
with one another, silver is a cheap and gold a dear commodity.
We ought naturally to expect, therefore, that there should
always be in the market not only a greater quantity, but a
greater value of silver than of gold. Let any man who has
a little of both compare his own silver with his gold plate,
and he will probably find that, not only the quantity, but
the value of the former greatly exceeds that of the latter.
Many people, besides, have a good deal of silver who have
no gold plate, which, even with those who have it, is generally
confined to watchcases, snuff-boxes, and such like trinkets,
of which the whole amount is seldom of great value. In the
British coin, indeed, the value of the gold preponderates
greatly, but it is not so in that of all countries. In the
coin of some countries the value of the two metals is nearly
equal. In the Scotch coin, before the union with England,
the gold preponderated very little, though it did somewhat,
as it appears by the accounts of the mint. In the coin of
many countries the silver preponderates. In France, the largest
sums are commonly paid in that metal, and it is there difficult
to get more gold than what is necessary to carry about in
your pocket. The superior value, however, of the silver plate
above that of the gold, which takes place in all countries,
will much more than compensate the preponderancy of the gold
coin above the silver, which takes place only in some countries.
Though,
in one sense of the word, silver always has been, and probably
always will be, much cheaper than gold; yet in another sense
gold may, perhaps, in the present state of the Spanish market,
be said to be somewhat cheaper than silver. A commodity may
be said to be dear or cheap, not only according to the absolute
greatness or smallness of its usual price, but according as
that price is more or less above the lowest for which it is
possible to bring it to market for any considerable time together.
This lowest price is that which barely replaces, with a moderate
profit, the stock which must be employed in bringing the commodity
thither. It is the price which affords nothing to the landlord,
of which rent makes not any component part, but which resolves
itself altogether into wages and profit. But, in the present
state of the Spanish market, gold is certainly somewhat nearer
to this lowest price than silver. The tax of the King of Spain
upon gold is only one-twentieth part of the standard metal,
or five per cent; whereas his tax upon silver amounts to one-tenth
part of it, or to ten per cent. In these taxes too, it has
already been observed, consists the whole rent of the greater
part of the gold and silver mines of Spanish America; and
that upon gold is still worse paid than that upon silver.
The profits of the undertakers of gold mines too, as they
more rarely make a fortune, must, in general, be still more
moderate than those of the undertakers of silver mines. The
price of Spanish gold, therefore, as it affords both less
rent and less profit, must, in the Spanish market, be somewhat
nearer to the lowest price for which it is possible to bring
it thither than the price of Spanish silver. When all expenses
are computed, the whole quantity of the one metal, it would
seem, cannot, in the Spanish market, be disposed of so advantageously
as the whole quantity of the other. The tax, indeed, of the
King of Portugal upon the gold of the Brazils is the same
with the ancient tax of the King of Spain upon the silver
of Mexico and Peru; or one-fifth part of the standard metal.
It may, therefore, be uncertain whether to the general market
of Europe the whole mass of American gold comes at a price
nearer to the lowest for which it is possible to bring it
thither than the whole mass of American silver.
The
price of diamonds and other precious stones may, perhaps,
be still nearer to the lowest price at which it is possible
to bring them to market than even the price of gold.
Though
it is not very probable that any part of a tax, which is not
only imposed upon one of the most proper subjects of taxation,
a mere luxury and superfluity, but which affords so very important
a revenue as the tax upon silver, will ever be given up as
long as it is possible to pay it; yet the same impossibility
of paying it, which in 1736 made it necessary to reduce it
from one-fifth to one-tenth, may in time make it necessary
to reduce it still further; in the same manner as it made
it necessary to reduce the tax upon gold to one-twentieth.
That the silver mines of Spanish America, like all other mines,
become gradually more expensive in the working, on account
of the greater depths at which it is necessary to carry on
the works, and of the greater expense of drawing out the water
and of supplying them with fresh air at those depths, is acknowledged
by everybody who has inquired into the state of those mines.
These
causes, which are equivalent to a growing scarcity of silver
(for a commodity may be said to grow scarcer when it becomes
more difficult and expensive to collect a certain quantity
of it) must, in time, produce one or other of the three following
events. The increase of the expense must either, first, be
compensated altogether by a proportionable increase in the
price of the metal; or, secondly, it must be compensated altogether
by a proportionable diminution of the tax upon silver; or,
thirdly, it must be compensated partly by the one, and partly
by the other of those two expedients. This third event is
very possible. As gold rose in its price in proportion to
silver, notwithstanding a great diminution of the tax upon
gold, so silver might rise in its price in proportion to labour
and commodities, notwithstanding an equal diminution of the
tax upon silver.
Such
successive reductions of the tax, however, though they may
not prevent altogether, must certainly retard, more or less,
the rise of the value of silver in the European market. In
consequence of such reductions many mines may be wrought which
could not be wrought before, because they could not afford
to pay the old tax; and the quantity of silver annually brought
to market must always be somewhat greater, and, therefore,
the value of any given quantity somewhat less, than it otherwise
would have been. In consequence of the reduction in 1736,
the value of silver in the European market, though it may
not at this day be lower than before that reduction, is, probably,
at least ten per cent lower than it would have been had the
Court of Spain continued to exact the old tax.
That,
notwithstanding this reduction, the value of silver has, during
the course of the present century, begun to rise somewhat
in the European market, the facts and arguments which have
been alleged above dispose me to believe, or more properly
to suspect and conjecture; for the best opinion which I can
form upon this subject scarce, perhaps, deserves the name
of belief. The rise, indeed, supposing there has been any,
has hitherto been so very small that after all that has been
said it may, perhaps, appear to many people uncertain, not
only whether this event has actually taken place; but whether
the contrary may not have taken place, or whether the value
of the silver may not still continue to fall in the European
market.
It
must be observed, however, that whatever may be the supposed
annual importation of gold and silver, there must be a certain
period at which the annual consumption of those metals will
be equal to that annual importation. Their consumption must
increase as their mass increases, or rather in a much greater
proportion. As their mass increases, their value diminishes.
They are more used and less cared for, and their consumption
consequently increases in a greater proportion than their
mass. After a certain period, therefore, the annual consumption
of those metals must, in this manner, become equal to their
annual importation, provided that importation is not continually
increasing; which, in the present times, is not supposed to
be the case.
If,
when the annual consumption has become equal to the annual
importation, the annual importation should gradually diminish,
the annual consumption may, for some time, exceed the annual
importation. The mass of those metals may gradually and insensibly
diminish, and their value gradually and insensibly rise, till
the annual importation become again stationary, the annual
consumption will gradually and insensibly accommodate itself
to what that annual importation can maintain.
GROUNDS
OF THE SUSPICION THAT
THE VALUE OF SILVER STILL
CONTINUES TO DECREASE
The
increase of the wealth of Europe, and the popular notion that,
as the quantity of the precious metals naturally increases
with the increase of wealth so their value diminishes as their
quantity increases, may, perhaps, dispose many people to believe
that their value still continues to fall in the European market;
and the still gradually increasing price of many parts of
the rude produce of land may confirm them still further in
this opinion.
That
that increase in the quantity of the precious metals, which
arises in any country from the increase of wealth, has no
tendency to diminish their value, I have endeavoured to show
already. Gold and silver naturally resort to a rich country,
for the same reason that all sorts of luxuries and curiosities
resort to it; not because they are cheaper there than in poorer
countries, but because they are dearer, or because a better
price is given for them. It is the superiority of price which
attracts them, and as soon as that superiority ceases, they
necessarily cease to go thither.
If
you except corn and such other vegetables as are raised altogether
by human industry, that all other sorts of rude produce, cattle,
poultry, game of all kinds, the useful fossils and minerals
of the earth, etc., naturally grow dearer as the society advances
in wealth and improvement, I have endeavoured to show already.
Though such commodities, therefore, come to exchange for a
greater quantity of silver than before, it will not from thence
follow that silver has become really cheaper, or will purchase
less labour than before, but that such commodities have become
really dearer, or will purchase more labour than before. It
is not their nominal price only, but their real price which
rises in the progress of improvement. The rise of their nominal
price is the effect, not of any degradation of the value of
silver, but of the rise in their real price.
DIFFERENT
EFFECTS OF THE PROGRESS OF
IMPROVEMENT UPON THREE
DIFFERENT SORTS OF RUDE PRODUCE
These
different sorts of rude produce may be divided into three
classes. The first comprehends those which it is scarce in
the power of human industry to multiply at all. The second,
those which it can multiply in proportion to the demand. The
third, those in which the efficacy of industry is either limited
or uncertain. In the progress of wealth and improvement, the
real price of the first may rise to any degree of extravagance,
and seems not to be limited by any certain boundary. That
of the second, though it may rise greatly, has, however, a
certain boundary beyond which it cannot well pass for any
considerable time together. That of the third, though its
natural tendency is to rise in the progress of improvement,
yet in the same degree of improvement it may sometimes happen
even to fall, sometimes to continue the same, and sometimes
to rise more or less, according as different accidents render
the efforts of human industry, in multiplying this sort of
rude produce, more or less successful.
FIRST
SORT
The
first sort of rude produce of which the price rises in the
progress of improvement is that which it is scarce in the
power of human industry to multiply at all. It consists in
those things which nature produces only in certain quantities,
and which, being of a very perishable nature, it is impossible
to accumulate together the produce of many different seasons.
Such are the greater part of rare and singular birds and fishes,
many different sorts of game, almost all wild-fowl, all birds
of passage in particular, as well as many other things. When
wealth and the luxury which accompanies it increase, the demand
for these is likely to increase with them, and no effort of
human industry may be able to increase the supply much beyond
what it was before this increase of the demand. The quantity
of such commodities, therefore, remaining the same, or nearly
the same, while the competition to purchase them is continually
increasing, their price may rise to any degree of extravagance,
and seems not to be limited by any certain boundary. If woodcocks
should become so fashionable as to sell for twenty guineas
apiece, no effort of human industry could increase the number
of those brought to market much beyond what it is at present.
The high price paid by the Romans, in the time of their greatest
grandeur, for rare birds and fishes, may in this manner easily
be accounted for. These prices were not the effects of the
low value of silver in those times, but of the high value
of such rarities and curiosities as human industry could not
multiply at pleasure. The real value of silver was higher
at Rome, for some time before and after the fall of the republic,
than it is through the greater part of Europe at present.
Three sestertii, equal to about sixpence sterling, was the
price which the republic paid for the modius or peck of the
tithe wheat of Sicily. This price, however, was probably below
the average market price, the obligation to deliver their
wheat at this rate being considered as a tax upon the Sicilian
farmers. When the Romans, therefore, had occasion to order
more corn than the tithe of wheat amounted to, they were bound
by capitulation to pay for the surplus at the rate of four
sestertii, or eightpence sterling, the peck; and this had
probably been reckoned the moderate and reasonable, that is,
the ordinary or average contract price of those times; it
is equal to about one-and-twenty shillings the quarter. Eight-and-twenty
shillings the quarter was, before the late years of scarcity,
the ordinary contract price of English wheat, which in quality
is inferior to the Sicilian, and generally sells for a lower
price in the European market. The value of silver, therefore,
in those ancient times, must have been to its value in the
present as three to four inversely; that is, three ounces
of silver would then have purchased the same quantity of labour
and commodities which four ounces will do at present. When
we read in Pliny, therefore, that Seius bought a white nightingale,
as a present for the Empress Agrippina, at a price of six
thousand sestertii, equal to about fifty pounds of our present
money; and that Asinius Celer purchased a surmullet at the
price of eight thousand sestertii, equal to about sixty-six
pounds thirteen shillings and fourpence of our present money,
the extravagance of those prices, how much soever it may surprise
us, is apt, notwithstanding, to appear to us about one-third
less than it really was. Their real price, the quantity of
labour and subsistence which was given away for them, was
about one-third more than their nominal price is apt to express
to us in the present times. Seius gave for the nightingale
the command of a quantity of labour and subsistence equal
to what L66 13s. 4d. would purchase in the present times;
and Asinius Celer gave for the surmullet the command of a
quantity equal to what L88 9 1/2d. would purchase. What occasioned
the extravagance of those high prices was, not so much the
abundance of silver as the abundance of labour and subsistence
of which those Romans had the disposal beyond what was necessary
for their own use. The quantity of silver of which they had
the disposal was a good deal less than what the command of
the same quantity of labour and subsistence would have procured
to them in the present times.
SECOND
SORT
The
second sort of rude procedure of which the price rises in
the progress of improvement is that which human industry can
multiply in proportion to the demand. It consists in those
useful plants and animals which, in uncultivated countries,
nature produces with such profuse abundance that they are
of little or no value, and which, as cultivation advances
are therefore forced to give place to some more profitable
produce. During a long period in the progress of improvement,
the quantity of these is continually diminishing, while at
the same time the demand for them is continually increasing.
Their real value, therefore, the real quantity of labour which
they will purchase or command, gradually rises, till at last
it gets so high as to render them as profitable a produce
as anything else which human industry can raise upon the most
fertile and best cultivated land. When it has got so high
it cannot well go higher. If it did, more land and more industry
would soon be employed to increase their quantity.
When
the price of cattle, for example, rises so high that it is
as profitable to cultivate land in order to raise food for
them as in order to raise food for man, it cannot well go
higher. If it did, more corn land would soon be turned into
pasture. The extension of tillage, by diminishing the quantity
of wild pasture, diminishes the quantity of butcher's meat
which the country naturally produces without labour or cultivation,
and by increasing the number of those who have either corn,
or, what comes to the same thing, the price of corn, to give
in exchange for it, increases the demand. The price of butcher's
meat, therefore, and consequently of cattle, must gradually
rise till it gets so high that it becomes as profitable to
employ the most fertile and best cultivated lands in raising
food for them as in raising corn. But it must always be late
in the progress of improvement before tillage can be so far
extended as to raise the price of cattle to this height; and
till it has got to this height, if the country is advancing
at all, their price must be continually rising. There are,
perhaps, some parts of Europe in which the price of cattle
has not yet got to this height. It had not got to this height
in any part of Scotland before the union. Had the Scotch cattle
been always confined to the market of Scotland, in a country
in which the quantity of land which can be applied to no other
purpose but the feeding of cattle is so great in proportion
to what can be applied to other purposes, it is scarce possible,
perhaps, that their price could ever have risen so high as
to render it profitable to cultivate land for the sake of
feeding them. In England, the price of cattle, it has already
been observed, seems, in the neighbourhood of London, to have
got to this height about the beginning of the last century;
but it was much later probably before it got to it through
the greater part of the remoter counties; in some of which,
perhaps, it may scarce yet have got to it. Of all the different
substances, however, which compose this second sort of rude
produce, cattle is, perhaps, that of which the price, in the
progress of improvement, first rises to this height.
Till
the price of cattle, indeed, has got to this height, it seems
scarce possible that the greater part, even of those lands
which are capable of the highest cultivation, can be completely
cultivated. In all farms too distant from any town to carry
manure from it, that is, in the far greater part of those
of every extensive country, the quantity of well-cultivated
land must be in proportion to the quantity of manure which
the farm itself produces; and this again must be in proportion
to the stock of cattle which are maintained upon it. The land
is manured either by pasturing the cattle upon it, or by feeding
them in the stable, and from thence carrying out their dung
to it. But unless the price of the cattle be sufficient to
pay both the rent and profit of cultivated land, the farmer
cannot afford to pasture them upon it; and he can still less
afford to feed them in the stable. It is with the produce
of improved and cultivated land only that cattle can be fed
in the stable; because to collect the scanty and scattered
produce of waste and unimproved lands would require too much
labour and be too expensive. If the price of cattle, therefore,
is not sufficient to pay for the produce of improved and cultivated
land, when they are allowed to pasture it, that price will
be still less sufficient to pay for that produce when it must
be collected with a good deal of additional labour, and brought
into the stable to them. In these circumstances, therefore,
no more cattle can, with profit, be fed in the stable than
what are necessary for tillage. But these can never afford
manure enough for keeping constantly in good condition all
the lands which they are capable of cultivating. What they
afford being insufficient for the whole farm will naturally
be reserved for the lands to which it can be most advantageously
or conveniently applied; the most fertile, or those, perhaps,
in the neighbourhood of the farmyard. These, therefore, will
be kept constantly in good condition and fit for tillage.
The rest will, the greater part of them, be allowed to lie
waste, producing scarce anything but some miserable pasture,
just sufficient to keep alive a few straggling, half-starved
cattle; the farm, though much understocked in proportion to
what would be necessary for its complete cultivation, being
very frequently overstocked in proportion to its actual produce.
A portion of this waste land, however, after having been pastured
in this wretched manner for six or seven years together, may
be ploughed up, when it will yield, perhaps, a poor crop or
two of bad oats, or of some other coarse grain, and then,
being entirely exhausted, it must be rested and pastured again
as before and another portion ploughed up to be in the same
manner exhausted and rested again in its turn. Such accordingly
was the general system of management all over the low country
of Scotland before the union. The lands which were kept constantly
well manured and in good condition seldom exceeded a third
or a fourth part of the whole farm, and sometimes did not
amount to a fifth or a sixth part of it. The rest were never
manured, but a certain portion of them was in its turn, notwithstanding,
regularly cultivated and exhausted. Under this system of management,
it is evident, even that part of the land of Scotland which
is capable of good cultivation could produce but little in
comparison of what it may be capable of producing. But how
disadvantageous soever this system may appear, yet before
the union the low price of cattle seems to have rendered it
almost unavoidable. If, notwithstanding a great rise in their
price, it still continues to prevail through a considerable
part of the country, it is owing, in many places, no doubt,
to ignorance and attachment to old customs, but in most places
to the unavoidable obstructions which the natural course of
things opposes to the immediate or speedy establishment of
a better system: first, to the poverty of the tenants, to
their not having yet had time to acquire a stock of cattle
sufficient to cultivate their lands more completely, the same
rise of price which would render it advantageous for them
to maintain a greater stock rendering it more difficult for
them to acquire it; and, secondly, to their not having yet
had time to put their lands in condition to maintain this
greater stock properly, supposing they were capable of acquiring
it. The increase of stock and the improvement of land are
two events which must go hand in hand, and of which the one
can nowhere much outrun the other. Without some increase of
stock there can be scarce any improvement of land, but there
can be no considerable increase of stock but in consequence
of a considerable improvement of land; because otherwise the
land could not maintain it. These natural obstructions to
the establishment of a better system cannot be removed but
by a long course of frugality and industry; and half a century
or a century more, perhaps, must pass away before the old
system, which is wearing out gradually, can be completely
abolished through all the different parts of the country.
Of all the commercial advantages, however, which Scotland
has derived from the union with England, this rise in the
price of cattle is, perhaps, the greatest. It has not only
raised the value of all highland estates, but it has, perhaps,
been the principal cause of the improvement of the low country.
In
all new colonies the great quantity of waste land, which can
for many years be applied to no other purpose but the feeding
of cattle, soon renders them extremely abundant, and in everything
great cheapness is the necessary consequence of great abundance.
Though all the cattle of the European colonies in America
were originally carried from Europe, they soon multiplied
so much there, and became of so little value that even horses
were allowed to run wild in the woods without any owner thinking
it worth while to claim them. It must be a long time, after
the first establishment of such colonies, before it can become
profitable to feed cattle upon the produce of cultivated land.
The same causes, therefore, the want of manure, and the disproportion
between the stock employed in cultivation, and the land which
it is destined to cultivate, are likely to introduce there
a system of husbandry not unlike that which still continues
to take place in so many parts of Scotland. Mr. Kalm, the
Swedish traveller, when he gives an account of the husbandry
of some of the English colonies in North America, as he found
it in 1749, observes, accordingly, that he can with difficulty
discover there the character of the English nation, so well
skilled in all the different branches of agriculture. They
make scarce any manure for their corn fields, he says; but
when one piece of ground has been exhausted by continual cropping,
they clear and cultivate another piece of fresh land; and
when that is exhausted, proceed to the third. Their cattle
are allowed to wander through the woods and other uncultivated
grounds, where they are half-starved; having long ago extirpated
almost all the annual grasses by cropping them too early in
the spring, before they had time to form their flowers, or
to shed their seeds. The annual grasses were, it seems, the
best natural grasses in that part of North America; and when
the Europeans first settled there, they used to grow very
thick, and to rise three or four feet high. A piece of ground
which, when he wrote, could not maintain one cow, would in
former times, he was assured, have maintained four, each of
which would have given four times the quantity of milk which
that one was capable of giving. The poorness of the pasture
had, in his opinion, occasioned the degradation of their cattle,
which degenerated sensibly from one generation to another.
They were probably not unlike that stunted breed which was
common all over Scotland thirty or forty years ago, and which
is now so much mended through the greater part of the low
country, not so much by a change of the breed, though that
expedient has been employed in some places, as by a more plentiful
method of feeding them.
Though
it is late, therefore, in the progress of improvement before
cattle can bring such a price as to render it profitable to
cultivate land for the sake of feeding them; yet of all the
different parts which compose this second sort of rude produce,
they are perhaps the first which bring this price; because
till they bring it, it seems impossible that improvement can
be brought near even to that degree of perfection to which
it has arrived in many parts of Europe.
As
cattle are among the first, so perhaps venison is among the
last parts of this sort of rude produce which bring this price.
The price of venison in Great Britain, how extravagant soever
it may appear, is not near sufficient to compensate the expense
of a deer park, as is well known to all those who have had
any experience in the feeding of deer. If it was otherwise,
the feeding of deer would soon become an article of common
farming, in the same manner as the feeding of those small
birds called Turdi was among the ancient Romans. Varro and
Columella assure us that it was a most profitable article.
The fattening of ortolans, birds of passage which arrive lean
in the country, is said to be so in some parts of France.
If venison continues in fashion, and the wealth and luxury
of Great Britain increase as they have done for some time
past, its price may very probably rise still higher than it
is at present.
Between
that period in the progress of improvement which brings to
its height the price of so necessary an article as cattle,
and that which brings to it the price of such a superfluity
as venison, there is a very long interval, in the course of
which many other sorts of rude produce gradually arrive at
their highest price, some sooner and some later, according
to different circumstances.
Thus
in every farm the offals of the barn and stables will maintain
a certain number of poultry. These, as they are fed with what
would otherwise be lost, are a mere save-all; and as they
cost the farmer scarce anything, so he can afford to sell
them for very little. Almost all that he gets is pure gain,
and their price can scarce be so low as to discourage him
from feeding this number. But in countries ill cultivated,
and therefore but thinly inhabited, the poultry, which are
thus raised without expense, are often fully sufficient to
supply the whole demand. In this state of things, therefore,
they are often as cheap as butcher's meat, or any other sort
of animal food. But the whole quantity of poultry, which the
farm in this manner produces without expense, must always
be much smaller than the whole quantity of butcher's meat
which is reared upon it; and in times of wealth and luxury
what is rare, with only nearly equal merit, is always preferred
to what is common. As wealth and luxury increase, therefore,
in consequence of improvement and cultivation, the price of
poultry gradually rises above that of butcher's meat, till
at last it gets so high that it becomes profitable to cultivate
land for the sake of feeding them. When it has got to this
height it cannot well go higher. If it did, more land would
soon be turned to this purpose. In several provinces of France,
the feeding of poultry is considered as a very important article
in rural economy, and sufficiently profitable to encourage
the farmer to raise a considerable quantity of Indian corn
and buck-wheat for this purpose. A middling farmer will there
sometimes have four hundred fowls in his yard. The feeding
of poultry seems scarce yet to be generally considered as
a matter of so much importance in England. They are certainly,
however, dearer in England than in France, as England receives
considerable supplies from France. In the progress of improvement,
the period at which every particular sort of animal food is
dearest must naturally be that which immediately precedes
the general practice of cultivating land for the sake of raising
it. For some time before this practice becomes general, the
scarcity must necessarily raise the price. After it has become
general, new methods of feeding are commonly fallen upon,
which enable the farmer to raise upon the same quantity of
ground a much greater quantity of that particular sort of
animal food. The plenty not only obliges him to sell cheaper,
but in consequence of these improvements he can afford to
sell cheaper; for if he could not afford it, the plenty would
not be of long continuance. It has been probably in this manner
that the introduction of clover, turnips, carrots, cabbage,
etc., has contributed to sink the common price of butcher's
meat in the London market somewhat below what it was about
the beginning of the last century.
The
hog, that finds his food among ordure and greedily devours
many things rejected by every other useful animal, is, like
poultry, originally kept as a save-all. As long as the number
of such animals, which can thus be reared at little or no
expense, is fully sufficient to supply the demand, this sort
of butcher's meat comes to market at a much lower price than
any other. But when the demand rises beyond what this quantity
can supply, when it becomes necessary to raise food on purpose
for feeding and fattening hogs, in the same manner as for
feeding and fattening other cattle, the price necessarily
rises, and becomes proportionably higher or lower than that
of other butcher's meat, according as the nature of the country,
and the state of its agriculture, happen to render the feeding
of hogs more or less expensive than that of other cattle.
In France, according to Mr. Buffon, the price of pork is nearly
equal to that of beef. In most parts of Great Britain it is
at present somewhat higher.
The
great rise in the price of both hogs and poultry has in Great
Britain been frequently imputed to the diminution of the number
of cottagers and other small occupiers of land; an event which
has in every part of Europe been the immediate forerunner
of improvement and better cultivation, but which at the same
time may have contributed to raise the price of those articles
both somewhat sooner and somewhat faster than it would otherwise
have risen. As the poorest family can often maintain a cat
or a dog without any expense, so the poorest occupiers of
land can commonly maintain a few poultry, or a sow and a few
pigs, at very little. The little offals of their own table,
their whey, skimmed milk, and buttermilk, supply those animals
with a part of their food, and they find the rest in the neighbouring
fields without doing any sensible damage to anybody. By diminishing
the number of those small occupiers, therefore, the quantity
of this sort of provisions, which is thus produced at little
or no expense, must certainly have been a good deal diminished,
and their price must consequently have been raised both sooner
and faster than it would otherwise have risen. Sooner or later,
however, in the progress of improvement, it must at any rate
have risen to the utmost height to which it is capable of
rising; or to the price which pays the labour and expense
of cultivating the land which furnishes them with food as
well as these are paid upon the greater part of other cultivated
land.
The
business of the dairy, like the feeding of hogs and poultry,
is originally carried on as a save-all. The cattle necessarily
kept upon the farm produce more milk than either the rearing
of their own young or the consumption of the farmer's family
requires; and they produce most at one particular season.
But of all the productions of land, milk is perhaps the most
perishable. In the warm season, when it is most abundant,
it will scarce keep four-and-twenty hours. The farmer, by
making it into fresh butter, stores a small part of it for
a week: by making it into salt butter, for a year: and by
making it into cheese, he stores a much greater part of it
for several years. Part of all these is reserved for the use
of his own family. The rest goes to market, in order to find
the best price which is to be had, and which can scarce be
so low as to discourage him from sending thither whatever
is over and above the use of his own family. If it is very
low, indeed, he will be likely to manage his dairy in a very
slovenly and dirty manner, and will scarce perhaps think it
worth while to have a particular room or building on purpose
for it, but will suffer the business to be carried on amidst
the smoke, filth, and nastiness of his own kitchen; as was
the case of almost all the farmers' dairies in Scotland thirty
or forty years ago, and as is the case of many of them still.
The same causes which gradually raise the price of butcher's
meat, the increase of the demand, and, in consequence of the
improvement of the country, the diminution of the quantity
which can be fed at little or no expense, raise, in the same
manner, that of the produce of the dairy, of which the price
naturally connects with that of butcher's meat, or with the
expense of feeding cattle. The increase of price pays for
more labour, care, and cleanliness. The dairy becomes more
worthy of the farmer's attention, and the quality of its produce
gradually improves. The price at last gets so high that it
becomes worth while to employ some of the most fertile and
best cultivated lands in feeding cattle merely for the purpose
of the dairy; and when it has got to this height, it cannot
well go higher. If it did, more land would soon be turned
to this purpose. It seems to have got to this height through
the greater part of England, where much good land is commonly
employed in this manner. If you except the neighbourhood of
a few considerable towns, it seems not yet to have got to
this height anywhere in Scotland, where common farmers seldom
employ much good land in raising food for cattle merely for
the purpose of the dairy. The price of the produce, though
it has risen very considerably within these few years, is
probably still too low to admit of it. The inferiority of
the quality, indeed, compared with that of the produce of
English dairies, is fully equal to that of the price. But
this inferiority of quality is, perhaps, rather the effect
of this lowness of price than the cause of it. Though the
quality was much better, the greater part of what is brought
to market could not, I apprehend, in the present circumstances
of the country, be disposed of at a much better price; and
the present price, it is probable would not pay the expense
of the land and labour necessary for producing a much better
quality. Though the greater part of England, notwithstanding
the superiority of price, the dairy is not reckoned a more
profitable employment of land than the raising of corn, or
the fattening of cattle, the two great objects of agriculture.
Through the greater part of Scotland, therefore, it cannot
yet be even so profitable.
The
lands of no country, it is evident, can ever be completely
cultivated and improved till once the price of every produce,
which human industry is obliged to raise upon them, has got
so high as to pay for the expense of complete improvement
and cultivation. In order to do this, the price of each particular
produce must be sufficient, first, to pay the rent of good
corn land, as it is that which regulates the rent of the greater
part of other cultivated land; and, secondly, to pay the labour
and expense of the farmer as well as they are commonly paid
upon good corn land; or, in other words, to replace with the
ordinary profits the stock which he employs about it. This
rise in the price of each particular produce must evidently
be previous to the improvement and cultivation of the land
which is destined for raising it. Gain is the end of all improvement,
and nothing could deserve that name of which loss was to be
the necessary consequence. But loss must be the necessary
consequence of improving land for the sake of a produce of
which the price could never bring back the expense. If the
complete improvement and cultivation of the country be, as
it most certainly is, the greatest of all public advantages,
this rise in the price of all those different sorts of rude
produce, instead of being considered as a public calamity,
ought to be regarded as the necessary forerunner and attendant
of the greatest of all public advantages.
This
rise, too, in the nominal or money-price of all those different
sorts of rude produce has been the effect, not of any degradation
in the value of silver, but of a rise in their real price.
They have become worth, not only a greater quantity of silver,
but a greater quantity of labour and subsistence than before.
As it costs a greater quantity of labour and subsistence to
bring them to market, so when they are brought thither, they
represent or are equivalent to a greater quantity.
THIRD
SORT
The
third and last sort of rude produce, of which the price naturally
rises in the progress of improvement, is that in which the
efficacy of human industry, in augmenting the quantity, is
either limited or uncertain. Though the real price of this
sort of rude produce, therefore, naturally tends to rise in
the progress of improvement, yet, according as different accidents
happen to render the efforts of human industry more or less
successful in augmenting the quantity, it may happen sometimes
even to fall, sometimes to continue the same in very different
periods of improvement, and sometimes to rise more or less
in the same period.
There
are some sorts of rude produce which nature has rendered a
kind of appendages to other sorts; so that the quantity of
the one which any country can afford, is necessarily limited
by that of the other. The quantity of wool or of raw hides,
for example, which any country can afford is necessarily limited
by the number of great and small cattle that are kept in it.
The state of its improvement, and the nature of its agriculture,
again necessarily determine this number.
The
same causes which, in the progress of improvement, gradually
raise the price of butcher's meat, should have the same effect,
it may be thought, upon the prices of wool and raw hides,
and raise them, too, nearly in the same proportion. It probably
would be so if, in the rude beginnings of improvement, the
market for the latter commodities was confined within as narrow
bounds as that for the former. But the extent of their respective
markets is commonly extremely different.
The
market for butcher's meat is almost everywhere confined to
the country which produces it. Ireland, and some part of British
America indeed, carry on a considerable trade in salt provisions;
but they are, I believe, the only countries in the commercial
world which do so, or which export to other countries any
considerable part of their butcher's meat.
The
market for wool and raw hides, on the contrary, is in the
rude beginnings of improvement very seldom confined to the
country which produces them. They can easily be transported
to distant countries, wool without any preparation, and raw
hides with very little: and as they are the materials of many
manufactures, the industry of other countries may occasion
a demand for them, though that of the country which produces
them might not occasion any.
In
countries ill cultivated, and therefore but thinly inhabited,
the price of the wool and the hide bears always a much greater
proportion to that of the whole beast than in countries where,
improvement and population being further advanced, there is
more demand for butcher's meat. Mr. Hume observes that in
the Saxon times the fleece was estimated at two-fifths of
the value of the whole sheep, and that this was much above
the proportion of its present estimation. In some provinces
of Spain, I have been assured, the sheep is frequently killed
merely for the sake of the fleece and the tallow. The carcase
is often left to rot upon the ground, or to be devoured by
beasts and birds of prey. If this sometimes happens even in
Spain, it happens almost constantly in Chili, at Buenos Ayres,
and in many other parts of Spanish America, where the horned
cattle are almost constantly killed merely for the sake of
the hide and the tallow. This, too, used to happen almost
constantly in Hispaniola, while it was infested by the Buccaneers,
and before the settlement, improvement, and populousness of
the French plantations (which now extend round the coast of
almost the whole western half of the island) had given some
value to the cattle of the Spaniards, who still continue to
possess, not only the eastern part of the coast, but the whole
inland and mountainous part of the country.
Though
in the progress of improvement and population the price of
the whole beast necessarily rises, yet the price of the carcase
is likely to be much more affected by this rise than that
of the wool and the hide. The market for the carcase, being
in the rude state of society confined always to the country
which produces it, must necessarily be extended in proportion
to the improvement and population of that country. But the
market for the wool and the hides even of a barbarous country
often extending to the whole commercial world, it can very
seldom be enlarged in the same proportion. The state of the
whole commercial world can seldom be much affected by the
improvement of any particular country; and the market for
such commodities may remain the same or very nearly the same
after such improvements as before. It should, however, in
the natural course of things rather upon the whole be somewhat
extended in consequence of them. If the manufactures, especially,
of which those commodities are the materials should ever come
to flourish in the country, the market, though it might not
be much enlarged, would at least be brought much nearer to
the place of growth than before; and the price of those materials
might at least be increased by what had usually been the expense
of transporting them to distant countries. Though it might
not rise therefore in the same proportion as that of butcher's
meat, it ought naturally to rise somewhat, and it ought certainly
not to fall.
In
England, however, notwithstanding the flourishing state of
its woollen manufacture, the price of English wool has fallen
very considerably since the time of Edward III. There are
many authentic records which demonstrate that during the reign
of that prince (towards the middle of the fourteenth century,
or about 1339) what was reckoned the moderate and reasonable
price of the tod, or twenty-eight pounds of English wool,
was not less than ten shillings of the money of those times,
containing at the rate of twentypence the ounce, six ounces
of silver Tower weight, equal to about thirty shillings of
our present money. In the present times, one-and-twenty shillings
the tod may be reckoned a good price for very good English
wool. The money-price of wool, therefore, in the time of Edward
III, was to its money-price in the present times as ten to
seven. The superiority of its real price was still greater.
At the rate of six shillings and eightpence the quarter, ten
shillings was in those ancient times the price of twelve bushels
of wheat. At the rate of twenty-eight shillings the quarter,
one-and-twenty shillings is in the present times the price
of six bushels only. The proportion between the real prices
of ancient and modern times, therefore, is as twelve to six,
or as two to one. In those ancient times a tod of wool would
have purchased twice the quantity of subsistence which it
will purchase at present; and consequently twice the quantity
of labour, if the real recompense of labour had been the same
in both periods.
This
degradation both in the real and nominal value of wool could
never have happened in consequence of the natural course of
things. It has accordingly been the effect of violence and
artifice: first, of the absolute prohibition of exporting
wool from England; secondly, of the permission of importing
it from Spain duty free; thirdly, of the prohibition of exporting
it from Ireland to any other country but England. In consequence
of these regulations the market for English wool, instead
of being somewhat extended in consequence of the improvement
of England, has been confined to the home market, where the
wool of several other countries is allowed to come into competition
with it, and where that of Ireland is forced into competition
with it. As the woollen manufactures, too, of Ireland are
fully as much discouraged as is consistent with justice and
fair dealing, the Irish can work up but a small part of their
own wool at home, and are, therefore, obliged to send a greater
proportion of it to Great Britain, the only market they are
allowed.
I
have not been able to find any such authentic records concerning
the price of raw hides in ancient times. Wool was commonly
paid as a subsidy to the king, and its valuation in that subsidy
ascertains, at least in some degree, what was its ordinary
price. But this seems not to have been the case with raw hides.
Fleetwood, however, from an account in 1425, between the prior
of Burcester Oxford and one of his canons, gives us their
price, at least as it was stated upon that particular occasion,
viz., five ox hides at twelve shillings; five cow hides at
seven shillings and threepence; thirty-six sheep skins of
two years old at nine shillings; sixteen calves skins at two
shillings. In 1425, twelve shillings contained about the same
quantity of silver as four-and-twenty shillings of our present
money. An ox hide, therefore, was in this account valued at
the same quantity of silver as 4s. four-fifths of our present
money. Its nominal price was a good deal lower than at present.
But at the rate of six shillings and eightpence the quarter,
twelve shillings would in those times have purchased fourteen
bushels and four-fifths of a bushel of wheat, which, at three
and sixpence the bushel, would in the present times cost 51s.
4d. An ox hide, therefore, would in those times have purchased
as much corn as ten shillings and threepence would purchase
at present. Its real value was equal to ten shillings and
threepence of our present money. In those ancient times, when
the cattle were half starved during the greater part of the
winter, we cannot suppose that they were of a very large size.
An ox hide which weighs four stone of sixteen pounds avoirdupois
is not in the present times reckoned a bad one; and in those
ancient times would probably have been reckoned a very good
one. But at half-a-crown the stone, which at this moment (February
1773) I understand to be the common price, such a hide would
at present cost only ten shillings. Though its nominal price,
therefore, is higher in the present than it was in those ancient
times, its real price, the real quantity of subsistence which
it will purchase or command, is rather somewhat lower. The
price of cow hides, as stated in the above account, is nearly
in the common proportion to that of ox hides. That of sheep
skins is a good deal above it. They had probably been sold
with the wool. That of calves skins, on the contrary, is greatly
below it. In countries where the price of cattle is very low,
the calves, which are not intended to be reared in order to
keep up the stock, are generally killed very young; as was
the case in Scotland twenty or thirty years ago. It saves
the milk, which their price would not pay for. Their skins,
therefore, are commonly good for little.
The
price of raw hides is a good deal lower at present than it
was a few years ago, owing probably to the taking off the
duty upon sealskins, and to the allowing, for a limited time,
the importation of raw hides from Ireland and from the plantations
duty free, which was done in 1769. Take the whole of the present
century at an average, their real price has probably been
somewhat higher than it was in those ancient times. The nature
of the commodity renders it not quite so proper for being
transported to distant markets as wool. It suffers more by
keeping. A salted hide is reckoned inferior to a fresh one,
and sells for a lower price. This circumstance must necessarily
have some tendency to sink the price of raw hides produced
in a country which does not manufacture them, but is obliged
to export them; and comparatively to raise that of those produced
in a country which does manufacture them. It must have some
tendency to sink their price in a barbarous, and to raise
it in an improved and manufacturing country. It must have
had some tendency, therefore, to sink it in ancient and to
raise it in modern times. Our tanners, besides, have not been
quite so successful as our clothiers in convincing the wisdom
of the nation that the safety of the commonwealth depends
upon the prosperity of their particular manufacture. They
have accordingly been much less favoured. The exportation
of raw hides has, indeed, been prohibited, and declared a
nuisance; but their importation from foreign countries has
been subjected to a duty; and though this duty has been taken
off from those of Ireland and the plantations (for the limited
time of five years only), yet Ireland has not been confined
to the market of Great Britain for the sale of its surplus
hides, or of those which are not manufactured at home. The
hides of common cattle have but within these few years been
put among the enumerated commodities which the plantations
can send nowhere but to the mother country; neither has the
commerce of Ireland been in this case oppressed hitherto in
order to support the manufactures of Great Britain.
Whatever
regulations tend to sink the price either of wool or of raw
hides below what it naturally would be must, in an improved
and cultivated country, have some tendency to raise the price
of butcher's meat. The price both of the great and small cattle,
which are fed on improved and cultivated land, must be sufficient
to pay the rent which the landlord and the profit which the
farmer has reason to expect from improved and cultivated land.
If it is not, they will soon cease to feed them. Whatever
part of this price, therefore, is not paid by the wool and
the hide must be paid by the carcase. The less there is paid
for the one, the more must be paid for the other. In what
manner this price is to be divided upon the different parts
of the beast is indifferent to the landlords and farmers,
provided it is all paid to them. In an improved and cultivated
country, therefore, their interest as landlords and farmers
cannot be much affected by such regulations, though their
interest as consumers may, by the rise in the price of provisions.
It would be quite otherwise, however, in an unimproved and
uncultivated country, where the greater part of the lands
could be applied to no other purpose but the feeding of cattle,
and where the wool and the hide made the principal part of
the value of those cattle. Their interest as landlords and
farmers would in this case be very deeply affected by such
regulations, and their interest as consumers very little.
The fall in the price of wool and the hide would not in this
case raise the price of the carcase, because the greater part
of the lands of the country being applicable to no other purpose
but the feeding of cattle, the same number would still continue
to be fed. The same quantity of butcher's meat would still
come to market. The demand for it would be no greater than
before. Its price, therefore, would be the same as before.
The whole price of cattle would fall, and along with it both
the rent and the profit of all those lands of which cattle
was the principal produce, that is, of the greater part of
the lands of the country. The perpetual prohibition of the
exportation of wool, which is commonly, but very falsely,
ascribed to Edward III, would, in the then circumstances of
the country, have been the most destructive regulation which
could well have been thought of. It would not only have reduced
the actual value of the greater part of the lands of the kingdom,
but by reducing the price of the most important species of
small cattle it would have retarded very much its subsequent
improvement.
The
wool of Scotland fell very considerably in its price in consequence
of the union with England, by which it was excluded from the
great market of Europe, and confined to the narrow one of
Great Britain. The value of the greater part of the lands
in the southern counties of Scotland, which are chiefly a
sheep country, would have been very deeply affected by this
event, had not the rise in the price of butcher's meat fully
compensated the fall in the price of wool.
As
the efficacy of human industry, in increasing the quantity
either of wool or of raw hides, is limited, so far as it depends
upon the produce of the country where it is exerted; so it
is uncertain so far as it depends upon the produce of other
countries. It so far depends, not so much upon the quantity
which they produce, as upon that which they do not manufacture;
and upon the restraints which they may or may not think proper
to impose upon the exportation of this sort of rude produce.
These circumstances, as they are altogether independent of
domestic industry, so they necessarily render the efficacy
of its efforts more or less uncertain. In multiplying this
sort of rude produce, therefore, the efficacy of human industry
is not only limited, but uncertain.
In
multiplying another very important sort of rude produce, the
quantity of fish that is brought to market, it is likewise
both limited and uncertain. It is limited by the local situation
of the country, by the proximity or distance of its different
provinces from the sea, by the number of its lakes and rivers,
and by what may be called the fertility or barrenness of those
seas, lakes, and rivers, as to this sort of rude produce.
As population increases, as the annual produce of the land
and labour of the country grows greater and greater, there
come to be more buyers of fish, and those buyers, too, have
a greater quantity and variety of other goods, or, what is
the same thing, the price of a greater quantity and variety
of other goods to buy with. But it will generally be impossible
to supply the great and extended market without employing
a quantity of labour greater than in proportion to what had
been requisite for supplying the narrow and confined one.
A market which, from requiring only one thousand, comes to
require annually ten thousand tons of fish, can seldom be
supplied without employing more than ten times the quantity
of labour which had before been sufficient to supply it. The
fish must generally be fought for at a greater distance, larger
vessels must be employed, and more expensive machinery of
every kind made use of. The real price of this commodity,
therefore, naturally rises in the progress of improvement.
It has accordingly done so, I believe, more or less in every
country.
Though
the success of a particular day's fishing may be a very uncertain
matter, yet, the local situation of the country being supposed,
the general efficacy of industry in bringing a certain quantity
of fish to market, taking the course of a year, or of several
years together, it may perhaps be thought is certain enough;
and it no doubt is so. As it depends more, however, upon the
local situation of the country than upon the state of its
wealth and industry; as upon this account it may in different
countries be the same in very different periods of improvement,
and very different in the same period; its connection with
the state of improvement is uncertain, and it is of this sort
of uncertainty that I am here speaking.
In
increasing the quantity of the different minerals and metals
which are drawn from the bowels of the earth, that of the
more precious ones particularly, the efficacy of human industry
seems not to be limited, but to be altogether uncertain.
The
quantity of the precious metals which is to be found in any
country is not limited by anything in its local situation,
such as the fertility or barrenness of its own mines. Those
metals frequently abound in countries which possess no mines.
Their quantity in every particular country seems to depend
upon two different circumstances; first, upon its power of
purchasing, upon the state of its industry, upon the annual
produce of its land and labour, in consequence of which it
can afford to employ a greater or a smaller quantity of labour
and subsistence in bringing or purchasing such superfluities
as gold and silver, either from its own mines or from those
of other countries; and, secondly, upon the fertility or barrenness
of the mines which may happen at any particular time to supply
the commercial world with those metals. The quantity of those
metals in the countries most remote from the mines must be
more or less affected by this fertility or barrenness, on
account of the easy and cheap transportation of those metals,
of their small bulk and great value. Their quantity in China
and Indostan must have been more or less affected by the abundance
of the mines of America.
So
far as their quantity in any particular country depends upon
the former of those two circumstances (the power of purchasing),
their real price, like that of all other luxuries and superfluities,
is likely to rise with the wealth and improvement of the country,
and to fall with its poverty and depression. Countries which
have a great quantity of labour and subsistence to spare can
afford to purchase any particular quantity of those metals
at the expense of a greater quantity of labour and subsistence
than countries which have less to spare.
So
far as their quantity in any particular country depends upon
the latter of those two circumstances (the fertility or barrenness
of the mines which happen to supply the commercial world),
their real price, the real quantity of labour and subsistence
which they will purchase or exchange for, will, no doubt,
sink more or less in proportion to the fertility, and rise
in proportion to the barrenness of those mines.
The
fertility or barrenness of the mines, however, which may happen
at any particular time to supply the commercial world, is
a circumstance which, it is evident, may have no sort of connection
with the state of industry in a particular country. It seems
even to have no very necessary connection with that of the
world in general. As arts and commerce, indeed, gradually
spread themselves over a greater and a greater part of the
earth, the search for new mines, being extended over a wider
surface, may have somewhat a better chance for being successful
than when confined within narrower bounds. The discovery of
new mines, however, as the old ones come to be gradually exhausted,
is a matter of the greatest uncertainty, and such as no human
skill or industry can ensure. All indications, it is acknowledged,
are doubtful, and the actual discovery and successful working
of a new mine can alone ascertain the reality of its value,
or even of its existence. In this search there seem to be
no certain limits either to the possible success or to the
possible disappointment of human industry. In the course of
a century or two, it is possible that new mines may be discovered
more fertile than any that have ever yet been known; and it
is just equally possible the most fertile mine then known
may be more barren than any that was wrought before the discovery
of the mines of America. Whether the one or the other of those
two events may happen to take place is of very little importance
to the real wealth and prosperity of the world, to the real
value of the annual produce of the land and labour of mankind.
Its nominal value, the quantity of gold and silver by which
this annual produce could be expressed or represented, would,
no doubt, be very different; but its real value, the real
quantity of labour which it could purchase or command, would
be precisely the same. A shilling might in the one case represent
no more labour than a penny does at present; and a penny in
the other might represent as much as a shilling does now.
But in the one case he who had a shilling in his pocket would
be no richer than he who has a penny at present; and in the
other he who had a penny would be just as rich as he who has
a shilling now. The cheapness and abundance of gold and silver
plate would be the sole advantage which the world could derive
from the one event, and the dearness and scarcity of those
trifling superfluities the only inconveniency it could suffer
from the other.
CONCLUSION
OF THE DIGRESSION
CONCERNING THE VARIATIONS IN
THE VALUE OF SILVER
The
greater part of the writers who have collected the money prices
of things in ancient times seem to have considered the low
money-price of corn, and of goods in general, or, in other
words, the high value of gold and silver, as a proof, not
only of the scarcity of those metals, but of the poverty and
barbarism of the country at the time when it took place. This
notion is connected with the system of political economy which
represents national wealth as consisting in the abundance,
and national poverty in the scarcity of gold and silver; a
system which I shall endeavour to explain and examine at great
length in the fourth book of this inquiry. I shall only observe
at present that the high value of the precious metals can
be no proof of the poverty or barbarism of any particular
country at the time when it took place. It is a proof only
of the barrenness of the mines which happened at that time
to supply the commercial world. A poor country, as it cannot
afford to buy more, so it can as little afford to pay dearer
for gold and silver than a rich one; and the value of those
metals, therefore, is not likely to be higher in the former
than in the latter. In China, a country much richer than any
part of Europe, the value of the precious metals is much higher
than in any part of Europe. As the wealth of Europe, indeed,
has increased greatly since the discovery of the mines of
America, so the value of gold and silver has gradually diminished.
This diminution of their value, however, has not been owing
to the increase of the real wealth of Europe, of the annual
produce of its land and labour, but to the accidental discovery
of more abundant mines than any that were known before. The
increase of the quantity of gold and silver in Europe, and
the increase of its manufactures and agriculture, are two
events which, though they have happened nearly about the same
time, yet have arisen from very different causes, and have
scarce any natural connection with one another. The one has
arisen from a mere accident, in which neither prudence nor
policy either had or could have any share. The other from
the fall of the feudal system, and from the establishment
of a government which afforded to industry the only encouragement
which it requires, some tolerable security that it shall enjoy
the fruits of its own labour. Poland, where the feudal system
still continues to take place, is at this day as beggarly
a country as it was before the discovery of America. The money
price of corn, however, has risen; the real value of the precious
metals has fallen in Poland, in the same manner as in other
parts of Europe. Their quantity, therefore, must have increased
there as in other places, and nearly in the same proportion
to the annual produce of its land and labour. This increase
of the quantity of those metals, however, has not, it seems,
increased that annual produce, has neither improved the manufactures
and agriculture of the country, nor mended the circumstances
of its inhabitants. Spain and Portugal, the countries which
possess the mines, are, after Poland, perhaps, the two most
beggarly countries in Europe. The value of the precious metals,
however, must be lower in Spain and Portugal than in any other
part of Europe; as they come from those countries to all other
parts of Europe, loaded, not only with a freight and an insurance,
but with the expense of smuggling, their exportation being
either prohibited, or subjected to a duty. In proportion to
the annual produce of the land and labour, therefore, their
quantity must be greater in those countries than in any other
part of Europe. Those countries, however, are poorer than
the greater part of Europe. Though the feudal system has been
abolished in Spain and Portugal, it has not been succeeded
by a much better.
As
the low value of gold and silver, therefore, is no proof of
the wealth and flourishing state of the country where it takes
place; so neither is their high value, or the low money price
either of goods in general, or of corn in particular, any
proof of its poverty and barbarism.
But
though the low money price either of goods in general, or
of corn in particular, be no proof of the poverty or barbarism
of the times, the low money price of some particular sorts
of goods, such as cattle, poultry, game of all kinds, etc.,
in proportion to that of corn, is a most decisive one. It
clearly demonstrates, first, their great abundance in proportion
to that of corn, and consequently the great extent of the
land which they occupied in proportion to what was occupied
by corn; and, secondly, the low value of this land in proportion
to that of corn land, and consequently the uncultivated and
unimproved state of the far greater part of the lands of the
country. It clearly demonstrates that the stock and population
of the country did not bear the same proportion to the extent
of its territory which they commonly do in civilised countries,
and that society was at that time, and in that country, but
in its infancy. From the high or low money price either of
goods in general, or of corn in particular, we can infer only
that the mines which at that time happened to supply the commercial
world with gold and silver were fertile or barren, not that
the country was rich or poor. But from the high or low money
price of some sorts of goods in proportion to that of others,
we can infer, with a degree of probability that approaches
almost to certainty, that it was rich or poor, that the greater
part of its lands were improved or unimproved, and that it
was either in a more or less barbarous state, or in a more
or less civilised one.
Any
rise in the money price of goods which proceeded altogether
from the degradation of the value of silver would affect all
sorts of goods equally, and raise their price universally
a third, or a fourth, or a fifth part higher, according as
silver happened to lose a third, or a fourth, or a fifth part
of its former value. But the rise in the price of provisions,
which has been the subject of so much reasoning and conversation,
does not affect all sorts of provisions equally. Taking the
course of the present century at an average, the price of
corn, it is acknowledged, even by those who account for this
rise by the degradation of the value of silver, has risen
much less than that of some other sorts of provisions. The
rise in the price of those other sorts of provisions, therefore,
cannot be owing altogether to the degradation of the value
of silver. Some other causes must be taken into the account,
and those which have been above assigned will, perhaps, without
having recourse to the supposed degradation of the value of
silver, sufficiently explain this rise in those particular
sorts of provisions of which the price has actually risen
in proportion to that of corn.
As
to the price of corn itself, it has, during the sixty-four
first years of the present century, and before the late extraordinary
course of bad seasons, been somewhat lower than it was during
the sixty-four last years of the preceding century. This fact
is attested, not only by the accounts of Windsor market, but
by the public fiars of all the different counties of Scotland,
and by the accounts of several different markets in France,
which have been collected with great diligence and fidelity
by Mr. Messance and by Mr. Dupre de St. Maur. The evidence
is more complete than could well have been expected in a matter
which is naturally so very difficult to be ascertained.
As
to the high price of corn during these last ten or twelve
years, it can be sufficiently accounted for from the badness
of the seasons, without supposing any degradation in the value
of silver. The opinion, therefore, that silver is continually
sinking in its value, seems not to be founded upon any good
observations, either upon the prices of corn, or upon those
of other provisions.
The
same quantity of silver, it may, perhaps, be said, will in
the present times, even according to the account which has
been here given, purchase a much smaller quantity of several
sorts of provisions than it would have done during some part
of the last century; and to ascertain whether this change
be owing to a rise in the value of those goods, or to a fall
in the value of silver, is only to establish a vain and useless
distinction, which can be of no sort of service to the man
who has only a certain quantity of silver to go to market
with, or a certain fixed revenue in money. I certainly do
not pretend that the knowledge of this distinction will enable
him to buy cheaper. It may not, however, upon that account
be altogether useless.
It
may be of some use to the public by affording an easy proof
of the prosperous condition of the country. If the rise in
the price of some sorts of provisions be owing altogether
to a fall in the value of silver, it is owing to a circumstance
from which nothing can be inferred but the fertility of the
American mines. The real wealth of the country, the annual
produce of its land and labour, may, notwithstanding this
circumstance, be either gradually declining, as in Portugal
and Poland; or gradually advancing, as in most other parts
of Europe. But if this rise in the price of some sorts of
provisions be owing to a rise in the real value of the land
which produces them, to its increased fertility, or, in consequence
of more extended improvement and good cultivation, to its
having been rendered fit for producing corn; it is owing to
a circumstance which indicates in the clearest manner the
prosperous and advancing state of the country. The land constitutes
by far the greatest, the most important, and the most durable
part of the wealth of every extensive country. It may surely
be of some use, or, at least, it may give some satisfaction
to the public, to have so decisive a proof of the increasing
value of by far the greatest, the most important, and the
most durable part of its wealth.
It
may, too, be of some use to the public in regulating the pecuniary
reward of some of its inferior servants. If this rise in the
price of some sorts of provisions be owing to a fall in the
value of silver, their pecuniary reward, provided it was not
too large before, ought certainly to be augmented in proportion
to the extent of this fall. If it is not augmented, their
real recompense will evidently be so much diminished. But
if this rise of price is owing to the increased value, in
consequence of the improved fertility of the land which produces
such provisions, it becomes a much nicer matter to judge either
in what proportion any pecuniary reward ought to be augmented,
or whether it ought to be augmented at all. The extension
of improvement and cultivation, as it necessarily raises more
or less, in proportion to the price of corn, that of every
sort of animal food, so it as necessarily lowers that of,
I believe, every sort of vegetable food. It raises the price
of animal food; because a great part of the land which produces
it, being rendered fit for producing corn, must afford to
the landlord and farmer the rent and profit of corn-land.
It lowers the price of vegetable food; because, by increasing
the fertility of the land, it increases its abundance. The
improvements of agriculture, too, introduce many sorts of
vegetable food, which, requiring less land and not more labour
than corn, come much cheaper to market. Such are potatoes
and maize, or what is called Indian corn, the two most important
improvements which the agriculture of Europe, perhaps, which
Europe itself has received from the great extension of its
commerce and navigation. Many sorts of vegetable food, besides,
which in the rude state of agriculture are confined to the
kitchen-garden, and raised only by the spade, come in its
improved state to be introduced into common fields, and to
be raised by the plough: such as turnips, carrots, cabbages,
etc. If in the progress of improvement, therefore, the real
price of one species of food necessarily rises, that of another
as necessarily falls, and it becomes a matter of more nicety
to judge how far the rise in the one may be compensated by
the fall in the other. When the real price of butcher's meat
has once got to its height (which, with regard to every sort,
except, perhaps, that of hogs' flesh, it seems to have done
through a great part of England more than a century ago),
any rise which can afterwards happen in that of any other
sort of animal food cannot much affect the circumstances of
the inferior ranks of people. The circumstances of the poor
through a great part of England cannot surely be so much distressed
by any rise in the price of poultry, fish, wild-fowl, or venison,
as they must be relieved by the fall in that of potatoes.
In
the present season of scarcity the high price of corn no doubt
distresses the poor. But in times of moderate plenty, when
corn is at its ordinary or average price, the natural rise
in the price of any other sort of rude produce cannot much
affect them. They suffer more, perhaps, by the artificial
rise which has been occasioned by taxes in the price of some
manufactured commodities; as of salt, soap, leather, candles,
malt, beer, and ale, etc.
EFFECTS
OF THE PROGRESS OF IMPROVEMENT UPON THE REAL
PRICE OF MANUFACTURES
It
is the natural effect of improvement, however, to diminish
gradually the real price of almost all manufactures. That
of the manufacturing workmanship diminishes, perhaps, in all
of them without exception. In consequence of better machinery,
of greater dexterity, and of a more proper division and distribution
of work, all of which are the natural effects of improvement,
a much smaller quantity of labour becomes requisite for executing
any particular piece of work, and though, in consequence of
the flourishing circumstances of the society, the real price
of labour should rise very considerably, yet the great diminution
of the quantity will generally much more than compensate the
greatest rise which can happen in the price.
There
are, indeed, a few manufactures in which the necessary rise
in the real price of the rude materials will more than compensate
all the advantages which improvement can introduce into the
execution of the work. In carpenters' and joiners' work, and
in the coarser sort of cabinet work, the necessary rise in
the real price of barren timber, in consequence of the improvement
of land, will more than compensate all the advantages which
can be derived from the best machinery, the greatest dexterity,
and the most proper division and distribution of work.
But
in all cases in which the real price of the rude materials
either does not rise at all, or does not rise very much, that
of the manufactured commodity sinks very considerably.
This
diminution of price has, in the course of the present and
preceding century, been most remarkable in those manufactures
of which the materials are the coarser metals. A better movement
of a watch, that about the middle of the last century could
have been bought for twenty pounds, may now perhaps be had
for twenty shillings. In the work of cutiers and locksmiths,
in all the toys which are made of the coarser metals, and
in all those goods which are commonly known by the name of
Birmingham and Sheffield ware, there has been, during the
same period, a very great reduction of price, though not altogether
so great as in watch-work. It has, however, been sufficient
to astonish the workmen of every other part of Europe, who
in many cases acknowledge that they can produce no work of
equal goodness for double, or even for triple the price. There
are perhaps no manufactures in which the division of labour
can be carried further, or in which the machinery employed
admits of a greater variety of improvements, than those of
which the materials are the coarser metals.
In
the clothing manufacture there has, during the same period,
been no such sensible reduction of price. The price of superfine
cloth, I have been assured, on the contrary, has, within these
five-and-twenty or thirty years, risen somewhat in proportion
to its quality; owing, it was said, to a considerable rise
in the price of the material, which consists altogether of
Spanish wool. That of the Yorkshire cloth, which is made altogether
of English wool, is said indeed, during the course of the
present century, to have fallen a good deal in proportion
to its quality. Quality, however, is so very disputable a
matter that I look upon all information of this kind as somewhat
uncertain. In the clothing manufacture, the division of labour
is nearly the same now as it was a century ago, and the machinery
employed is not very different. There may, however, have been
some small improvements in both, which may have occasioned
some reduction of price.
But
the reduction will appear much more sensible and undeniable
if we compare the price of this manufacture in the present
times with what it was in a much remoter period, towards the
end of the fifteenth century, when the labour was probably
much less subdivided, and the machinery employed much more
imperfect, than it is at present.
In
1487, being the 4th of Henry VII, it was enacted that "whosoever
shall sell by retail a broad yard of the finest scarlet grained,
or of other grained cloth of the finest making, above sixteen
shillings, shall forfeit forty shillings for every yard so
sold." Sixteen shillings, therefore, containing about the
same quantity of silver as four-and-twenty shillings of our
present money, was, at that time, reckoned not an unreasonable
price for a yard of the finest cloth; and as this is a sumptuary
law, such cloth, it is probable, had usually been sold somewhat
dearer. A guinea may be reckoned the highest price in the
present times. Even though the quality of the cloths, therefore,
should be supposed equal, and that of the present times is
most probably much superior, yet, even upon this supposition,
the money price of the finest cloth appears to have been considerably
reduced since the end of the fifteenth century. But its real
price has been much more reduced. Six shillings and eightpence
was then, and long afterwards, reckoned the average price
of a quarter of wheat. Sixteen shillings, therefore, was the
price of two quarters and more than three bushels of wheat.
Valuing a quarter of wheat in the present times at eight-and-twenty
shillings, the real price of a yard of fine cloth must, in
those times, have been equal to at least three pounds six
shillings and sixpence of our present money. The man who bought
it must have parted with the command of a quantity of labour
and subsistence equal to what that sum would purchase in the
present times.
The
reduction in the real price of the coarse manufacture, though
considerable, has not been so great as in that of the fine.
In
1643, being the 3rd of Edward IV, it was enacted that "no
servant in husbandry, nor common labourer, nor servant to
any artificer inhabiting out of a city or burgh shall use
or wear in their clothing any cloth above two shillings the
broad yard." In the 3rd of Edward IV, two shillings contained
very nearly the same quantity of silver as four of our present
money. But the Yorkshire cloth which is now sold at four shillings
the yard is probably much superior to any that was then made
for the wearing of the very poorest order of common servants.
Even the money price of their clothing, therefore, may, in
proportion to the quality, be somewhat cheaper in the present
than it was in those ancient times. The real price is certainly
a good deal cheaper. Tenpence was then reckoned what is called
the moderate and reasonable price of a bushel of wheat. Two
shillings, therefore, was the price of two bushels and near
two pecks of wheat, which in the present times, at three shillings
and sixpence the bushel, would be worth eight shillings and
ninepence. For a yard of this cloth the poor servant must
have parted with the power of purchasing a quantity of subsistence
equal to what eight shillings and ninepence would purchase
in the present times. This is a sumptuary law too, restraining
the luxury and extravagance of the poor. Their clothing, therefore,
had commonly been much more expensive.
The
same order of people are, by the same law, prohibited from
wearing hose, of which the price should exceed fourteenpence
the pair, equal to about eight-and-twentypence of our present
money. But fourteenpence was in those times the price of a
bushel and near two pecks of wheat, which, in the present
times, at three and sixpence the bushel, would cost five shillings
and threepence. We should in the present times consider this
as a very high price for a pair of stockings, to a servant
of the poorest and lowest order. He must, however, in those
times have paid what was really equivalent to this price for
them.
In
the time of Edward IV the art of knitting stockings was probably
not known in any part of Europe. Their hose were made of common
cloth, which may have been one of the causes of their dearness.
The first person that wore stockings in England is said to
have been Queen Elizabeth. She received them as a present
from the Spanish ambassador.
Both
in the coarse and in the fine woollen manufacture, the machinery
employed was much more imperfect in those ancient than it
is in the present times. It has since received three very
capital improvements, besides, probably, many smaller ones
of which it may be difficult to ascertain either the number
or the importance. The three capital improvements are: first,
the exchange of the rock and spindle for the spinning-wheel,
which, with the same quantity of labour, will perform more
than double the quantity of work. Secondly, the use of several
very ingenious machines which facilitate and abridge in a
still greater proportion the winding of the worsted and woollen
yarn, or the proper arrangement of the warp and woof before
they are put into the loom; an operation which, previous to
the invention of those machines, must have been extremely
tedious and troublesome. Thirdly, the employment of the fulling
mill for thickening the cloth, instead of treading it in water.
Neither wind nor water mills of any kind were known in England
so early as the beginning of the sixteenth century, nor, so
far as I know, in any other part of Europe north of the Alps.
They had been introduced into Italy some time before.
The
consideration of these circumstances may, perhaps, in some
measure explain to us why the real price both of the coarse
and of the fine manufacture was so much higher in those ancient
than it is in the present times. It cost a greater quantity
of labour to bring the goods to market. When they were brought
thither, therefore, they must have purchased or exchanged
for the price of a greater quantity.
The
coarse manufacture probably was, in those ancient times, carried
on in England, in the same manner as it always has been in
countries where arts and manufactures are in their infancy.
It was probably a household manufacture, in which every different
part of the work was occasionally performed by all the different
members of almost every private family; but so as to be their
work only when they had nothing else to do, and not to be
the principal business from which any of them derived the
greater part of their subsistence. The work which is performed
in this manner, it has already been observed, comes always
much cheaper to market than that which is the principal or
sole fund of the workman's subsistence. The fine manufacture,
on the other hand, was not in those times carried on in England,
but in the rich and commercial country of Flanders; and it
was probably conducted then, in the same manner as now, by
people who derived the whole, or the principal part of their
subsistence from it. It was, besides, a foreign manufacture,
and must have paid some duty, the ancient custom of tonnage
and poundage at least, to the king. This duty, indeed, would
not probably be very great. It was not then the policy of
Europe to restrain, by high duties, the importation of foreign
manufactures, but rather to encourage it, in order that merchants
might be enabled to supply, at as easy a rate as possible,
the great men with the conveniences and luxuries which they
wanted, and which the industry of their own country could
not afford them.
The
consideration of these circumstances may perhaps in some measure
explain to us why, in those ancient times, the real price
of the coarse manufacture was, in proportion to that of the
fine, so much lower than in the present times.
CONCLUSION
OF THE CHAPTER
I
shall conclude this very long chapter with observing that
every improvement in the circumstances of the society tends
either directly or indirectly to raise the real rent of land,
to increase the real wealth of the landlord, his power of
purchasing the labour, or the produce of the labour of other
people.
The
extension of improvement and cultivation tends to raise it
directly. The landlord's share of the produce necessarily
increases with the increase of the produce.
That
rise in the real price of those parts of the rude produce
of land, which is first the effect of extended improvement
and cultivation, and afterwards the cause of their being still
further extended, the rise in the price of cattle, for example,
tends too to raise the rent of land directly, and in a still
greater proportion. The real value of the landlord's share,
his real command of the labour of other people, not only rises
with the real value of the produce, but the proportion of
his share to the whole produce rises with it. That produce,
after the rise in its real price, requires no more labour
to collect it than before. A smaller proportion of it will,
therefore, be sufficient to replace, with the ordinary profit,
the stock which employs that labour. A greater proportion
of it must, consequently, belong to the landlord.
All
those improvements in the productive powers of labour, which
tend directly to reduce the real price of manufactures, tend
indirectly to raise the real rent of land. The landlord exchanges
that part of his rude produce, which is over and above his
own consumption, or what comes to the same thing, the price
of that part of it, for manufactured produce. Whatever reduces
the real price of the latter, raises that of the former. An
equal quantity of the former becomes thereby equivalent to
a greater quantity of the latter; and the landlord is enabled
to purchase a greater quantity of the conveniences, ornaments,
or luxuries, which he has occasion for.
Every
increase in the real wealth of the society, every increase
in the quantity of useful labour employed within it, tends
indirectly to raise the real rent of land. A certain proportion
of this labour naturally goes to the land. A greater number
of men and cattle are employed in its cultivation, the produce
increases with the increase of the stock which is thus employed
in raising it, and the rent increases with the produce.
The
contrary circumstances, the neglect of cultivation and improvement,
the fall in the real price of any part of the rude produce
of land, the rise in the real price of manufactures from the
decay of manufacturing art and industry, the declension of
the real wealth of the society, all tend, on the other hand,
to lower the real rent of land, to reduce the real wealth
of the landlord, to diminish his power of purchasing either
the labour, or the produce of the labour of other people.
The
whole annual produce of the land and labour of every country,
or what comes to the same thing, the whole price of that annual
produce, naturally divides itself, it has already been observed,
into three parts; the rent of land, the wages of labour, and
the profits of stock; and constitutes a revenue to three different
orders of people; to those who live by rent, to those who
live by wages, and to those who live by profit. These are
the three great, original, and constituent orders of every
civilised society, from whose revenue that of every other
order is ultimately derived.
The
interest of the first of those three great orders, it appears
from what has been just now said, is strictly and inseparably
connected with the general interest of the society. Whatever
either promotes or obstructs the one, necessarily promotes
or obstructs the other. When the public deliberates concerning
any regulation of commerce or police, the proprietors of land
never can mislead it, with a view to promote the interest
of their own particular order; at least, if they have any
tolerable knowledge of that interest. They are, indeed, too
often defective in this tolerable knowledge. They are the
only one of the three orders whose revenue costs them neither
labour nor care, but comes to them, as it were, of its own
accord, and independent of any plan or project of their own.
That indolence, which is the natural effect of the ease and
security of their situation, renders them too often, not only
ignorant, but incapable of that application of mind which
is necessary in order to foresee and understand the consequences
of any public regulation.
The
interest of the second order, that of those who live by wages,
is as strictly connected with the interest of the society
as that of the first. The wages of the labourer, it has already
been shown, are never so high as when the demand for labour
is continually rising, or when the quantity employed is every
year increasing considerably. When this real wealth of the
society becomes stationary, his wages are soon reduced to
what is barely enough to enable him to bring up a family,
or to continue the race of labourers. When the society declines,
they fall even below this. The order of proprietors may, perhaps,
gain more by the prosperity of the society than that of labourers:
but there is no order that suffers so cruelly from its decline.
But though the interest of the labourer is strictly connected
with that of the society, he is incapable either of comprehending
that interest or of understanding its connection with his
own. His condition leaves him no time to receive the necessary
information, and his education and habits are commonly such
as to render him unfit to judge even though he was fully informed.
In the public deliberations, therefore, his voice is little
heard and less regarded, except upon some particular occasions,
when his clamour is animated, set on and supported by his
employers, not for his, but their own particular purposes.
His
employers constitute the third order, that of those who live
by profit. It is the stock that is employed for the sake of
profit which puts into motion the greater part of the useful
labour of every society. The plans and projects of the employers
of stock regulate and direct all the most important operations
of labour, and profit is the end proposed by all those plans
and projects. But the rate of profit does not, like rent and
wages, rise with the prosperity and fall with the declension
of the society. On the contrary, it is naturally low in rich
and high in poor countries, and it is always highest in the
countries which are going fastest to ruin. The interest of
this third order, therefore, has not the same connection with
the general interest of the society as that of the other two.
Merchants and master manufacturers are, in this order, the
two classes of people who commonly employ the largest capitals,
and who by their wealth draw to themselves the greatest share
of the public consideration. As during their whole lives they
are engaged in plans and projects, they have frequently more
acuteness of understanding than the greater part of country
gentlemen. As their thoughts, however, are commonly exercised
rather about the interest of their own particular branch of
business, than about that of the society, their judgment,
even when given with the greatest candour (which it has not
been upon every occasion) is much more to be depended upon
with regard to the former of those two objects than with regard
to the latter. Their superiority over the country gentleman
is not so much in their knowledge of the public interest,
as in their having a better knowledge of their own interest
than he has of his. It is by this superior knowledge of their
own interest that they have frequently imposed upon his generosity,
and persuaded him to give up both his own interest and that
of the public, from a very simple but honest conviction that
their interest, and not his, was the interest of the public.
The interest of the dealers, however, in any particular branch
of trade or manufactures, is always in some respects different
from, and even opposite to, that of the public. To widen the
market and to narrow the competition, is always the interest
of the dealers. To widen the market may frequently be agreeable
enough to the interest of the public; but to narrow the competition
must always be against it, and can serve only to enable the
dealers, by raising their profits above what they naturally
would be, to levy, for their own benefit, an absurd tax upon
the rest of their fellow-citizens. The proposal of any new
law or regulation of commerce which comes from this order
ought always to be listened to with great precaution, and
ought never to be adopted till after having been long and
carefully examined, not only with the most scrupulous, but
with the most suspicious attention. It comes from an order
of men whose interest is never exactly the same with that
of the public, who have generally an interest to deceive and
even to oppress the public, and who accordingly have, upon
many occasions, both deceived and oppressed it.
TABLES REFERRED TO IN CHAPTER 11, PART 3
Price of the Average of The average Price
Quarter of the different of each Year in
Years Wheat Prices of Money of the
XII each Year the same Year present Times
L s. d. L. s. d. L. s. d.
1202 - 12 - - - - 1 16 -
1205 - 12 - - 13 5 2 - 3
- 13 4
- 15 -
1223 - 12 - - - - 1 16 -
1237 - 3 4 - - - - 10 -
1243 - 2 - - - - - 6 -
1244 - 2 - - - - - 6 -
1246 - 16 - - - - 2 8 -
1247 - 13 4 - - - 2 - -
1257 1 4 - - - - 3 12 -
1258 1 - - - 17 - 2 11 -
- 15 -
- 16 -
1270 4 16 - 5 12 - 16 16 -
6 8 -
1286 - 2 8 - 9 4 1 8 -
- 16 -
---------------
Total L35 9 3
---------------
Average Price L2 19 1 1/4
Price of the Average of The average Price
Quarter of the different of each Year in
Years Wheat Prices of Money of the
XII each Year the same Year present Times
L s. d. L. s. d. L. s. d.
1287 - 3 4 - - - - 10 -
1288 - - 8 - 3 - 1/4 - 9 - 3/4
- 1 -
- 1 4
- 1 6
- 1 8
- 2 -
- 3 4
- 9 4
1289 - 12 - - 10 1 3/4 1 10 4 1/2
- 6 -
- 2 -
- 10 8
1 - -
1290 - 16 - - - - 2 8 -
1294 - 16 - - - - 2 8 -
1302 - 4 - - - - - 12 -
1309 - 7 2 - - - 1 1 6
1315 1 - - - - - 3 - -
1316 1 - - 1 10 6 4 11 6
1 10 -
1 12 -
2 - -
1317 2 4 - 1 19 6 5 18 6
- 14 -
2 13 -
4 - -
- 6 8
1336 - 2 - - - - - 6 -
1338 - 3 4 - - - - 10 -
---------------
Total L23 4 11 1/4
---------------
Average Price L1 18 8
Price of the Average of The average Price
Quarter of the different of each Year in
Years Wheat Prices of Money of the
XII each Year the same Year present Times
L s. d. L. s. d. L. s. d.
1339 - 9 - - - - 1 7 -
1349 - 2 - - - - - 5 2
1359 1 6 8 - - - 3 2 2
1361 - 2 - - - - - 4 8
1363 - 15 - - - - 1 15 -
1369 1 - - 1 2 - 2 9 4
1 4 -
1379 - 4 - - - - - 9 4
1387 - 2 - - - - - 4 8
1390 - 13 4 - 14 5 1 13 7
- 14 -
- 16 -
1401 - 16 - - - - 1 17 4
1407 - 4 4 3/4 - 3 10 - 8 11
- 3 4
1416 - 16 - - - - 1 12 -
---------------
Total L15 9 4
---------------
Average Price L1 5 9 1/3
Price of the Average of The average Price
Quarter of the different of each Year in
Years Wheat Prices of Money of the
XII each Year the same Year present Times
L s. d. L. s. d. L. s. d.
1423 - 8 - - - - - 16 -
1425 - 4 - - - - - 8 -
1434 1 6 8 - - - 2 13 4
1435 - 5 4 - - - - 10 8
1439 1 - - 1 3 4 2 6 8
1 6 8
1440 1 4 - - - - 2 8 -
1444 - 4 4 - 4 2 - 8 4
- 4 -
1445 - 4 6 - - - - 9 -
1447 - 8 - - - - - 16 -
1448 - 6 8 - - - - 13 4
1449 - 5 - - - - - 10 -
1452 - 8 - - - - - 16 -
---------------
Total L12 15 4
---------------
Average Price L1 1 3 1/2
Price of the Average of The average Price
Quarter of the different of each Year in
Years Wheat Prices of Money of the
XII each Year the same Year present Times
L s. d. L. s. d. L. s. d.
1453 - 5 4 - - - - 10 8
1455 - 1 2 - - - - 2 4
1457 - 7 8 - - - - 15 4
1459 - 5 - - - - - 10 -
1460 - 8 - - - - - 16 -
1463 - 2 - - 1 10 - 3 8
- 1 8
1464 - 6 8 - - - - 10 -
1486 1 4 - - - - 1 17 -
1491 - 14 8 - - - 1 2 -
1494 - 4 - - - - - 6 -
1495 - 3 4 - - - - 5 -
1497 1 - - - - - 1 11 -
--------------
Total L8 9 -
--------------
Average Price - 14 1
Price of the Average of The average Price
Quarter of the different of each Year in
Years Wheat Prices of Money of the
XII each Year the same Year present Times
L s. d. L. s. d. L. s. d.
1499 - 4 - - - - - 6 -
1504 - 5 8 - - - - 8 6
1521 1 - - - - - 1 10 -
1551 - 8 - - - - - 2 -
1553 - 8 - - - - - 8 -
1554 - 8 - - - - - 8 -
1555 - 8 - - - - - 8 -
1556 - 8 - - - - - 8 -
1557 - 4 - - 17 8 1/2 - 17 8 1/2
- 5 -
- 8 -
2 13 4
1558 - 8 - - - - - 8 -
1559 - 8 - - - - - 8 -
1560 - 8 - - - - - 8 -
--------------
Total L6 0 2 1/2
--------------
Average Price - 10 - 5/12
Price of the Average of The average Price
Quarter of the different of each Year in
Years Wheat Prices of Money of the
XII each Year the same Year present Times
L s. d. L. s. d. L. s. d.
1561 - 8 - - - - - 8 -
1562 - 8 - - - - - 8 -
1574 2 16 - 2 - - 2 - -
1 4 -
1587 3 4 - - - - 3 4 -
1594 2 16 - - - - 2 16 -
1595 2 13 - - - - 2 13 -
1596 4 - - - - - 4 - -
1597 5 4 - 4 12 - 4 12 -
4 - -
1598 2 16 8 - - - 2 16 8
1599 1 19 2 - - - 1 19 2
1600 1 17 8 - - - 1 17 8
1601 1 14 10 - - - 1 14 10
---------------
Total L28 9 4
---------------
Average Price L2 7 5 1/3
Prices of the Quarter of nine Bushels of the best or highest
priced Wheat at Windsor Market, on Lady-day and Michaelmas, from
1595 to 1764, both inclusive; the Price of each Year being the
medium between the highest Prices of those Two Market Days.
Years Years
L. s. d. L. s. d.
1595 - 2 0 0 1621 - 1 10 4
1596 - 2 8 0 1622 - 2 18 8
1597 - 3 9 6 1623 - 2 12 0
1598 - 2 16 8 1624 - 2 8 0
1599 - 1 19 2 1625 - 2 12 0
1600 - 1 17 8 1626 - 2 9 4
1601 - 1 14 10 1627 - 1 16 0
1602 - 1 9 4 1628 - 1 8 0
1603 - 1 15 4 1629 - 2 2 0
1604 - 1 10 8 1630 - 2 15 8
1605 - 1 15 10 1631 - 3 8 0
1606 - 1 13 0 1632 - 2 13 4
1607 - 1 16 8 1633 - 2 18 0
1608 - 2 16 8 1634 - 2 16 0
1609 - 2 10 0 1635 - 2 16 0
1610 - 1 15 10 1636 - 2 16 8
1611 - 1 18 8 --------------
1612 - 2 2 4 16) 40 0 0
1613 - 2 8 8 --------------
1614 - 2 1 8 1/2 L2 10 0
1615 - 1 18 8
1616 - 2 0 4
1617 - 2 8 8
1618 - 2 6 8
1619 - 1 15 4
1620 - 1 10 4
--------------
26) 54 0 6 1/2
--------------
L2 1 6 9/12
Wheat per Wheat per
Years quarter Years quarter
L. s. d. L. s. d.
1637 - 2 13 0 Brought over 79 14 10
1638 - 2 17 4 1671 - 2 2 0
1639 - 2 4 10 1672 - 2 1 0
1640 - 2 4 8 1673 - 2 6 8
1641 - 2 8 0 1674 - 3 8 8
1642 - 0 0 0* 1675 - 3 4 8
1643 - 0 0 0 1676 - 1 18 0
1644 - 0 0 0 1677 - 2 2 0
1645 - 0 0 0 1678 - 2 19 0
1646 - 2 8 0 1679 - 3 0 0
1647 - 3 13 8 1680 - 2 5 0
1648 - 4 5 0 1681 - 2 6 8
1649 - 4 0 0 1682 - 2 4 0
1650 - 3 16 8 1683 - 2 0 0
1651 - 3 13 4 1684 - 2 4 0
1652 - 2 9 6 1685 - 2 6 8
1653 - 1 15 6 1686 - 1 14 0
1654 - 1 6 0 1687 - 1 5 2
1655 - 1 13 4 1688 - 2 6 0
1656 - 2 3 0 1689 - 1 10 0
1657 - 2 6 8 1690 - 1 14 8
1658 - 3 5 0 1691 - 1 14 0
1659 - 3 6 0 1692 - 2 6 8
1660 - 2 16 6 1693 - 3 7 8
1661 - 3 10 0 1694 - 3 4 0
1662 - 3 14 0 1695 - 2 13 0
1663 - 2 17 0 1696 - 3 11 0
1664 - 2 0 6 1697 - 3 0 0
1665 - 2 9 4 1698 - 3 8 4
1666 - 1 16 0 1699 - 3 4 0
1667 - 1 16 0 1700 - 2 0 0
1668 - 2 0 0 ---------------
1669 - 2 4 4 60) 153 1 8
1670 - 2 1 8 ---------------
-------------- L2 11 0 1/3
Carry over L79 14 10
*Wanting in the account. The year 1646 supplied by Bishop Fleetwood.
Wheat per Wheat per
Years quarter Years quarter
L. s. d. L. s. d.
1701 - 1 17 8 Brought over 69 8 8
1702 - 1 9 6 1734 - 1 18 10
1703 - 1 16 0 1735 - 2 3 0
1704 - 2 6 6 1736 - 2 0 4
1705 - 1 10 0 1737 - 1 18 0
1706 - 1 6 0 1738 - 1 15 6
1707 - 1 8 6 1739 - 1 18 6
1708 - 2 1 6 1740 - 2 10 8
1709 - 3 18 6 1741 - 2 6 8
1710 - 3 18 0 1742 - 1 14 0
1711 - 2 14 0 1743 - 1 4 10
1712 - 2 6 4 1744 - 1 4 10
1713 - 2 11 0 1745 - 1 7 6
1714 - 2 10 4 1746 - 1 19 0
1715 - 2 3 0 1747 - 1 14 10
1716 - 2 8 0 1748 - 1 17 0
1717 - 2 5 8 1749 - 1 17 0
1718 - 1 18 10 1750 - 1 12 6
1719 - 1 15 0 1751 - 1 18 6
1720 - 1 17 0 1752 - 2 1 10
1721 - 1 17 6 1753 - 2 4 8
1722 - 1 16 0 1754 - 1 14 8
1723 - 1 14 8 1755 - 1 13 10
1724 - 1 17 0 1756 - 2 5 3
1725 - 2 8 6 1757 - 3 0 0
1726 - 2 6 0 1758 - 2 10 0
1727 - 2 2 0 1759 - 1 19 10
1728 - 2 14 6 1760 - 1 16 6
1729 - 2 6 10 1761 - 1 10 3
1730 - 1 16 6 1762 - 1 19 0
1731 - 1 12 10 1763 - 2 0 9
1732 - 1 6 8 1764 - 2 6 9
1733 - 1 8 4 ---------------
-------------- 64) 129 13 6
Carry over L69 8 8 ---------------
L2 0 6 9/32
Years Years
L. s. d. L. s. d.
1731 - 1 12 10 1741 - 2 6 8
1732 - 1 6 8 1742 - 1 14 0
1733 - 1 8 4 1743 - 1 4 10
1734 - 1 18 10 1744 - 1 4 10
1735 - 2 3 0 1745 - 1 7 6
1736 - 2 0 4 1746 - 1 19 0
1737 - 1 18 0 1747 - 1 14 10
1738 - 1 15 6 1748 - 1 17 0
1739 - 1 18 6 1749 - 1 17 0
1740 - 2 10 8 1750 - 1 12 6
-------------- --------------
10) 18 12 8 10) 16 18 2
-------------- ---------------
L1 17 3 1/5 L1 13 9 4/5