Book
One:
OF
THE CAUSES OF IMPROVEMENT IN THE PRODUCTIVE POWERS OF LABOUR,
AND OF THE ORDER ACCORDING TO WHICH ITS PRODUCE IS NATURALLY
DISTRIBUTED AMONG THE DIFFERENT RANKS OF THE PEOPLE.
CHAPTER
IV
Of the Origin and Use of Money
When
the division of labour has been once thoroughly established,
it is but a very small part of a man's wants which the produce
of his own labour can supply. He supplies the far greater part
of them by exchanging that surplus part of the produce of his
own labour, which is over and above his own consumption, for
such parts of the produce of other men's labour as he has occasion
for. Every man thus lives by exchanging, or becomes in some
measure a merchant, and the society itself grows to be what
is properly a commercial society.
But
when the division of labour first began to take place, this
power of exchanging must frequently have been very much clogged
and embarrassed in its operations. One man, we shall suppose,
has more of a certain commodity than he himself has occasion
for, while another has less. The former consequently would be
glad to dispose of, and the latter to purchase, a part of this
superfluity. But if this latter should chance to have nothing
that the former stands in need of, no exchange can be made between
them. The butcher has more meat in his shop than he himself
can consume, and the brewer and the baker would each of them
be willing to purchase a part of it. But they have nothing to
offer in exchange, except the different productions of their
respective trades, and the butcher is already provided with
all the bread and beer which he has immediate occasion for.
No exchange can, in this case, be made between them. He cannot
be their merchant, nor they his customers; and they are all
of them thus mutually less serviceable to one another. In order
to avoid the inconveniency of such situations, every prudent
man in every period of society, after the first establishment
of the division of labour, must naturally have endeavoured to
manage his affairs in such a manner as to have at alltimes by
him, besides the peculiar produce of his own industry, a certain
quantity of some one commodity or other, such as he imagined
few people would be likely to refuse in exchange for the produce
of their industry.
Many
different commodities, it is probable, were successively both
thought of and employed for this purpose. In the rude ages of
society, cattle are said to have been the common instrument
of commerce; and, though they must have been a most inconvenient
one, yet in old times we find things were frequently valued
according to the number of cattle which had been given in exchange
for them. The armour of Diomede, says Homer, cost only nine
oxen; but that of Glaucus cost an hundred oxen. Salt is said
to be the common instrument of commerce and exchanges in Abyssinia;
a species of shells in some parts of the coast of India; dried
cod at Newfoundland; tobacco in Virginia; sugar in some of our
West India colonies; hides or dressed leather in some other
countries; and there is at this day a village in Scotland where
it is not uncommon, I am told, for a workman to carry nails
instead of money to the baker's shop or the alehouse.
In
all countries, however, men seem at last to have been determined
by irresistible reasons to give the preference, for this employment,
to metals above every other commodity. Metals can not only be
kept with as little loss as any other commodity, scarce anything
being less perishable than they are, but they can likewise,
without any loss, be divided into any number of parts, as by
fusion those parts can easily be reunited again; a quality which
no other equally durable commodities possess, and which more
than any other quality renders them fit to be the instruments
of commerce and circulation. The man who wanted to buy salt,
for example, and had nothing but cattle to give in exchange
for it, must have been obliged to buy salt to the value of a
whole ox, or a whole sheep at a time. He could seldom buy less
than this, because what he was to give for it could seldom be
divided without loss; and if he had a mind to buy more, he must,
for the same reasons, have been obliged to buy double or triple
the quantity, the value, to wit, of two or three oxen, or of
two or three sheep. If, on the contrary, instead of sheep or
oxen, he had metals to give in exchange for it, he could easily
proportion the quantity of the metal to the precise quantity
of the commodity which he had immediate occasion for.
Different
metals have been made use of by different nations for this purpose.
Iron was the common instrument of commerce among the ancient
Spartans; copper among the ancient Romans; and gold and silver
among all rich and commercial nations.
Those
metals seem originally to have been made use of for this purpose
in rude bars, without any stamp or coinage. Thus we are told
by Pliny, upon the authority of Timaeus, an ancient historian,
that, till the time of Servius Tullius, the Romans had no coined
money, but made use of unstamped bars of copper, to purchase
whatever they had occasion for. These bars, therefore, performed
at this time the function of money.
The
use of metals in this rude state was attended with two very
considerable inconveniencies; first, with the trouble of weighing;
and, secondly, with that of assaying them. In the precious metals,
where a small difference in the quantity makes a great difference
in the value, even the business of weighing, with proper exactness,
requires at least very accurate weights and scales. The weighing
of gold in particular is an operation of some nicety. In the
coarser metals, indeed, where a small error would be of little
consequence, less accuracy would, no doubt, be necessary. Yet
we should find it excessively troublesome, if every time a poor
man had occasion either to buy or sell a farthing's worth of
goods, he was obliged to weigh the farthing. The operation of
assaying is still more difficult, still more tedious, and, unless
a part of the metal is fairly melted in the crucible, with proper
dissolvents, any conclusion that can be drawn from it, is extremely
uncertain. Before the institution of coined money, however,
unless they went through this tedious and difficult operation,
people must always have been liable to the grossest frauds and
impositions, and instead of a pound weight of pure silver, or
pure copper, might receive in exchange for their goods an adulterated
composition of the coarsest and cheapest materials, which had,
however, in their outward appearance, been made to resemble
those metals. To prevent such abuses, to facilitate exchanges,
and thereby to encourage all sorts of industry and commerce,
it has been found necessary, in all countries that have made
any considerable advances towards improvement, to affix a public
stamp upon certain quantities of such particular metals as were
in those countries commonly made use of to purchase goods. Hence
the origin of coined money, and of those public offices called
mints; institutions exactly of the same nature with those of
the aulnagers and stamp-masters of woolen and linen cloth. All
of them are equally meant to ascertain, by means of a public
stamp, the quantity and uniform goodness of those different
commodities when brought to market.
The
first public stamps of this kind that were affixed to the current
metals, seem in many cases to have been intended to ascertain,
what it was both most difficult and most important to ascertain,
the goodness or fineness of the metal, and to have resembled
the sterling mark which is at present affixed to plate and bars
of silver, or the Spanish mark which is sometimes affixed to
ingots of gold, and which being struck only upon one side of
the piece, and not covering the whole surface, ascertains the
fineness, but not the weight of the metal. Abraham weighs to
Ephron the four hundred shekels of silver which he had agreed
to pay for the field of Machpelah. They are said, however, to
be the current money of the merchant, and yet are received by
weight and not by tale, in the same manner as ingots of gold
and bars of silver are at present. The revenues of the ancient
Saxon kings of England are said to have been paid, not in money
but in kind, that is, in victuals and provisions of all sorts.
William the Conqueror introduced the custom of paying them in
money. This money, however, was, for a long time, received at
the exchequer, by weight and not by tale.
The
inconveniency and difficulty of weighing those metals with exactness
gave occasion to the institution of coins, of which the stamp,
covering entirely both sides of the piece and sometimes the
edges too, was supposed to ascertain not only the fineness,
but the weight of the metal. Such coins, therefore, were received
by tale as at present, without the trouble of weighing.
The
denominations of those coins seem originally to have expressed
the weight or quantity of metal contained in them. In the time
of Servius Tullius, who first coined money at Rome, the Roman
as or pondo contained a Roman pound of good copper. It was divided
in the same manner as our Troyes pound, into twelve ounces,
each of which contained a real ounce of good copper. The English
pound sterling, in the time of Edward I, contained a pound,
Tower weight, of silver, of a known fineness. The Tower pound
seems to have been something more than the Roman pound, and
something less than the Troyes pound. This last was not introduced
into the mint of England till the 18th of Henry VIII. The French
livre contained in the time of Charlemagne a pound, Troyes weight,
of silver of a known fineness. The fair of Troyes in Champaign
was at that time frequented by all the nations of Europe, and
the weights and measures of so famous a market were generally
known and esteemed. The Scots money pound contained, from the
time of Alexander the First to that of Robert Bruce, a pound
of silver of the same weight and fineness with the English pound
sterling. English, French, and Scots pennies, too, contained
all of them originally a real pennyweight of silver, the twentieth
part of an ounce, and the two-hundred-and-fortieth part of a
pound. The shilling too seems originally to have been the denomination
of a weight. When wheat is at twelve shillings the quarter,
says an ancient statute of Henry III, then wastel bread of a
farthing shall weigh eleven shillings and four pence. The proportion,
however, between the shilling and either the penny on the one
hand, or the pound on the other, seems not to have been so constant
and uniform as that between the penny and the pound. During
the first race of the kings of France, the French sou or shilling
appears upon different occasions to have contained five, twelve,
twenty, and forty pennies. Among the ancient Saxons a shilling
appears at one time to have contained only five pennies, and
it is not improbable that it may have been as variable among
them as among their neighbours, the ancient Franks. From the
time of Charlemagne among the French, and from that of William
the Conqueror among the English, the proportion between the
pound, the shilling, and the penny, seems to have been uniformly
the same as at present, though the value of each has been very
different. For in every country of the world, I believe, the
avarice and injustice of princes and sovereign states, abusing
the confidence of their subjects, have by degrees diminished
the real quantity of metal, which had been originally contained
in their coins. The Roman as, in the latter ages of the Republic,
was reduced to the twenty-fourth part of its original value,
and, instead of weighing a pound, came to weigh only half an
ounce. The English pound and penny contain at present about
a third only; the Scots pound and penny about a thirty-sixth;
and the French pound and penny about a sixty-sixth part of their
original value. By means of those operations the princes and
sovereign states which performed them were enabled, in appearance,
to pay their debts and to fulfil their engagements with a smaller
quantity of silver than would otherwise have been requisite.
It was indeed in appearance only; for their creditors were really
defrauded of a part of what was due to them. All other debtors
in the state were allowed the same privilege, and might pay
with the same nominal sum of the new and debased coin whatever
they had borrowed in the old. Such operations, therefore, have
always proved favourable to the debtor, and ruinous to the creditor,
and have sometimes produced a greater and more universal revolution
in the fortunes of private persons, than could have been occasioned
by a very great public calamity.
It
is in this manner that money has become in all civilised nations
the universal instrument of commerce, by the intervention of
which goods of all kinds are bought and sold, or exchanged for
one another.
What
are the rules which men naturally observe in exchanging them
either for money or for one another, I shall now proceed to
examine. These rules determine what may be called the relative
or exchangeable value of goods.
The
word value, it is to be observed, has two different meanings,
and sometimes expresses the utility of some particular object,
and sometimes the power of purchasing other goods which the
possession of that object conveys. The one may be called "value
in use"; the other, "value in exchange." The things which have
the greatest value in use have frequently little or no value
in exchange; and, on the contrary, those which have the greatest
value in exchange have frequently little or no value in use.
Nothing is more useful than water: but it will purchase scarce
anything; scarce anything can be had in exchange for it. A diamond,
on the contrary, has scarce any value in use; but a very great
quantity of other goods may frequently be had in exchange for
it.
In
order to investigate the principles which regulate the exchangeable
value of commodities, I shall endeavour to show:
First,
what is the real measure of this exchangeable value; or, wherein
consists the real price of all commodities.
Secondly,
what are the different parts of which this real price is composed
or made up.
And,
lastly, what are the different circumstances which sometimes
raise some or all of these different parts of price above, and
sometimes sink them below their natural or ordinary rate; or,
what are the causes which sometimes hinder the market price,
that is, the actual price of commodities, from coinciding exactly
with what may be called their natural price.
I
shall endeavour to explain, as fully and distinctly as I can,
those three subjects in the three following chapters, for which
I must very earnestly entreat both the patience and attention
of the reader: his patience in order to examine a detail which
may perhaps in some places appear unnecessarily tedious; and
his attention in order to understand what may, perhaps, after
the fullest explication which I am capable of giving of it,
appear still in some degree obscure. I am always willing to
run some hazard of being tedious in order to be sure that I
am perspicuous; and after taking the utmost pains that I can
to be perspicuous, some obscurity may still appear to remain
upon a subject in its own nature extremely abstracted.
...
..
..