Book
One:
OF
THE CAUSES OF IMPROVEMENT IN THE PRODUCTIVE POWERS OF LABOUR,
AND OF THE ORDER ACCORDING TO WHICH ITS PRODUCE IS NATURALLY
DISTRIBUTED AMONG THE DIFFERENT RANKS OF THE PEOPLE.
CHAPTER
V
Of the Real and Nominal Price of Commodities, or their Price
in Labour,
and their Price in Money
Every
man is rich or poor according to the degree in which he can
afford to enjoy the necessaries, conveniences, and amusements
of human life. But after the division of labour has once thoroughly
taken place, it is but a very small part of these with which
a man's own labour can supply him. The far greater part of them
he must derive from the labour of other people, and he must
be rich or poor according to the quantity of that labour which
he can command, or which he can afford to purchase. The value
of any commodity, therefore, to the person who possesses it,
and who means not to use or consume it himself, but to exchange
it for other commodities, is equal to the quantity of labour
which it enables him to purchase or command. Labour, therefore,
is the real measure of the exchangeable value of all commodities.
The
real price of everything, what everything really costs to the
man who wants to acquire it, is the toil and trouble of acquiring
it. What everything is really worth to the man who has acquired
it, and who wants to dispose of it or exchange it for something
else, is the toil and trouble which it can save to himself,
and which it can impose upon other people. What is bought with
money or with goods is purchased by labour as much as what we
acquire by the toil of our own body. That money or those goods
indeed save us this toil. They contain the value of a certain
quantity of labour which we exchange for what is supposed at
the time to contain the value of an equal quantity. Labour was
the first price, the original purchase-money that was paid for
all things. It was not by gold or by silver, but by labour,
that all the wealth of the world was originally purchased; and
its value, to those who possess it, and who want to exchange
it for some new productions, is precisely equal to the quantity
of labour which it can enable them to purchase or command.
Wealth,
as Mr. Hobbes says, is power. But the person who either acquires,
or succeeds to a great fortune, does not necessarily acquire
or succeed to any political power, either civil or military.
His fortune may, perhaps, afford him the means of acquiring
both, but the mere possession of that fortune does not necessarily
convey to him either. The power which that possession immediately
and directly conveys to him, is the power of purchasing; a certain
command over all the labour, or over all the produce of labour,
which is then in the market. His fortune is greater or less,
precisely in proportion to the extent of this power; or to the
quantity either of other men's labour, or, what is the same
thing, of the produce of other men's labour, which it enables
him to purchase or command. The exchangeable value of everything
must always be precisely equal to the extent of this power which
it conveys to its owner.
But
though labour be the real measure of the exchangeable value
of all commodities, it is not that by which their value is commonly
estimated. It is of difficult to ascertain the proportion between
two different quantities of labour. The time spent in two different
sorts of work will not always alone determine this proportion.
The different degrees of hardship endured, and of ingenuity
exercised, must likewise be taken into account. There may be
more labour in an hour's hard work than in two hours' easy business;
or in an hour's application to a trade which it cost ten years'
labour to learn, than in a month's industry at an ordinary and
obvious employment. But it is not easy to find any accurate
measure either of hardship or ingenuity. In exchanging, indeed,
the different productions of different sorts of labour for one
another, some allowance is commonly made for both. It is adjusted,
however, not by any accurate measure, but by the higgling and
bargaining of the market, according to that sort of rough equality
which, though not exact, is sufficient for carrying on the business
of common life.
Every
commodity, besides, is more frequently exchanged for, and thereby
compared with, other commodities than with labour. It is more
natural, therefore, to estimate its exchangeable value by the
quantity of some other commodity than by that of the labour
which it can purchase. The greater part of people, too, understand
better what is meant by a quantity of a particular commodity
than by a quantity of labour. The one is a plain palpable object;
the other an abstract notion, which, though it can be made sufficiently
intelligible, is not altogether so natural and obvious.
But
when barter ceases, and money has become the common instrument
of commerce, every particular commodity is more frequently exchanged
for money than for any other commodity. The butcher seldom carries
his beef or his mutton to the baker, or the brewer, in order
to exchange them for bread or for beer; but he carries them
to the market, where he exchanges them for money, and afterwards
exchanges that money for bread and for beer. The quantity of
money which he gets for them regulates, too, the quantity of
bread and beer which he can afterwards purchase. It is more
natural and obvious to him, therefore, to estimate their value
by the quantity of money, the commodity for which he immediately
exchanges them, than by that of bread and beer, the commodities
for which he can exchange them only by the intervention of another
commodity; and rather to say that his butcher's meat is worth
threepence or fourpence a pound, than that it is worth three
or four pounds of bread, or three or four quarts of small beer.
Hence it comes to pass that the exchangeable value of every
commodity is more frequently estimated by the quantity of money,
than by the quantity either of labour or of any other commodity
which can be had in exchange for it.
Gold
and silver, however, like every other commodity, vary in their
value, are sometimes cheaper and sometimes dearer, sometimes
of easier and sometimes of more difficult purchase. The quantity
of labour which any particular quantity of them can purchase
or command, or the quantity of other goods which it will exchange
for, depends always upon the fertility or barrenness of the
mines which happen to be known about the time when such exchanges
are made. The discovery of the abundant mines of America reduced,
in the sixteenth century, the value of gold and silver in Europe
to about a third of what it had been before. As it costs less
labour to bring those metals from the mine to the market, so
when they were brought thither they could purchase or command
less labour; and this revolution in their value, though perhaps
the greatest, is by no means the only one of which history gives
some account. But as a measure of quantity, such as the natural
foot, fathom, or handful, which is continually varying in its
own quantity, can never be an accurate measure of the quantity
of other things; so a commodity which is itself continually
varying in its own value, can never be an accurate measure of
the value of other commodities. Equal quantities of labour,
at all times and places, may be said to be of equal value to
the labourer. In his ordinary state of health, strength and
spirits; in the ordinary degree of his skill and dexterity,
he must always laydown the same portion of his ease, his liberty,
and his happiness. The price which he pays must always be the
same, whatever may be the quantity of goods which he receives
in return for it. Of these, indeed, it may sometimes purchase
a greater and sometimes a smaller quantity; but it is their
value which varies, not that of the labour which purchases them.
At all times and places that is dear which it is difficult to
come at, or which it costs much labour to acquire; and that
cheap which is to be had easily, or with very little labour.
Labour alone, therefore, never varying in its own value, is
alone the ultimate and real standard by which the value of all
commodities can at all times and places be estimated and compared.
It is their real price; money is their nominal price only.
But
though equal quantities of labour are always of equal value
to the labourer, yet to the person who employs him they appear
sometimes to be of greater and sometimes of smaller value. He
purchases them sometimes with a greater and sometimes with a
smaller quantity of goods, and to him the price of labour seems
to vary like that of all other things. It appears to him dear
in the one case, and cheap in the other. In reality, however,
it is the goods which are cheap in the one case, and dear in
the other.
In
this popular sense, therefore, labour, like commodities, may
be said to have a real and a nominal price. Its real price may
be said to consist in the quantity of the necessaries and conveniences
of life which are given for it; its nominal price, in the quantity
of money. The labourer is rich or poor, is well or ill rewarded,
in proportion to the real, not to the nominal price of his labour.
The
distinction between the real and the nominal price of commodities
and labour is not a matter of mere speculation, but may sometimes
be of considerable use in practice. The same real price is always
of the same value; but on account of the variations in the value
of gold and silver, the same nominal price is sometimes of very
different values. When a landed estate, therefore, is sold with
a reservation of a perpetual rent, if it is intended that this
rent should always be of the same value, it is of importance
to the family in whose favour it is reserved that it should
not consist in a particular sum of money. Its value would in
this case be liable to variations of two different kinds; first,
to those which arise from the different quantities of gold and
silver which are contained at different times in coin of the
same denomination; and, secondly, to those which arise from
the different values of equal quantities of gold and silver
at different times.
Princes
and sovereign states have frequently fancied that they had a
temporary interest to diminish the quantity of pure metal contained
in their coins; but they seldom have fancied that they had any
to augment it. The quantity of metal contained in the coins,
I believe of all nations, has, accordingly, been almost continually
diminishing, and hardly ever augmenting. Such variations, therefore,
tend almost always to diminish the value of a money rent.
The
discovery of the mines of America diminished the value of gold
and silver in Europe. This diminution, it is commonly supposed,
though I apprehend without any certain proof, is still going
on gradually, and is likely to continue to do so for a long
time. Upon this supposition, therefore, such variations are
more likely to diminish than to augment the value of a money
rent, even though it should be stipulated to be paid, not in
such a quantity of coined money of such a denomination (in so
many pounds sterling, for example), but in so many ounces either
of pure silver, or of silver of a certain standard.
The
rents which have been reserved in corn have preserved their
value much better than those which have been reserved in money,
even where the denomination of the coin has not been altered.
By the 18th of Elizabeth it was enacted that a third of the
rent of all college leases should be reserved in corn, to be
paid, either in kind, or according to the current prices at
the nearest public market. The money arising from this corn
rent, though originally but a third of the whole, is in the
present times, according to Dr. Blackstone, commonly near double
of what arises from the other two-thirds. The old money rents
of colleges must, according to this account, have sunk almost
to a fourth part of their ancient value; or are worth little
more than a fourth part of the corn which they were formerly
worth. But since the reign of Philip and Mary the denomination
of the English coin has undergone little or no alteration, and
the same number of pounds, shillings and pence have contained
very nearly the same quantity of pure silver. This degradation,
therefore, in the value of the money rents of colleges, has
arisen altogether from the degradation in the value of silver.
When
the degradation in the value of silver is combined with the
diminution of the quantity of it contained in the coin of the
same denomination, the loss is frequently still greater. In
Scotland, where the denomination of the coin has undergone much
greater alterations than it ever did in England, and in France,
where it has undergone still greater than it ever did in Scotland,
some ancient rents, originally of considerable value, have in
this manner been reduced almost to nothing.
Equal
quantities of labour will at distant times be purchased more
nearly with equal quantities of corn, the subsistence of the
labourer, than with equal quantities of gold and silver, or
perhaps of any other commodity. Equal quantities of corn, therefore,
will, at distant times, be more nearly of the same real value,
or enable the possessor to purchase or command more nearly the
same quantity of the labour of other people. They will do this,
I say, more nearly than equal quantities of almost any other
commodity; for even equal quantities of corn will not do it
exactly. The subsistence of the labourer, or the real price
of labour, as I shall endeavour to show hereafter, is very different
upon different occasions; more liberal in a society advancing
to opulence than in one that is standing still; and in one that
is standing still than in one that is going backwards. Every
other commodity, however, will at any particular time purchase
a greater or smaller quantity of labour in proportion to the
quantity of subsistence which it can purchase at that time.
A rent therefore reserved in corn is liable only to the variations
in the quantity of labour which a certain quantity of corn can
purchase. But a rent reserved in any other commodity is liable
not only to the variations in the quantity of labour which any
particular quantity of corn can purchase, but to the variations
in the quantity of corn which can be purchased by any particular
quantity of that commodity.
Though
the real value of a corn rent, it is to be observed, however,
varies much less from century to century than that of a money
rent, it varies much more from year to year. The money price
of labour, as I shall endeavour to show hereafter, does not
fluctuate from year to year with the money price of corn, but
seems to be everywhere accommodated, not to the temporary or
occasional, but to the average or ordinary price of that necessary
of life. The average or ordinary price of corn again is regulated,
as I shall likewise endeavour to show hereafter, by the value
of silver, by the richness or barrenness of the mines which
supply the market with that metal, or by the quantity of labour
which must be employed, and consequently of corn which must
be consumed, in order to bring any particular quantity of silver
from the mine to the market. But the value of silver, though
it sometimes varies greatly from century to century, seldom
varies much from year to year, but frequently continues the
same, or very nearly the same, for half a century or a century
together. The ordinary or average money price of corn, therefore,
may, during so long a period, continue the same or very nearly
the same too, and along with it the money price of labour, provided,
at least, the society continues, in other respects, in the same
or nearly in the same condition. In the meantime the temporary
and occasional price of corn may frequently be double, one year,
of what it had been the year before, or fluctuate, for example,
from five and twenty to fifty shillings the quarter. But when
corn is at the latter price, not only the nominal, but the real
value of a corn rent will be double of what it is when at the
former, or will command double the quantity either of labour
or of the greater part of other commodities; the money price
of labour, and along with it that of most other things, continuing
the same during all these fluctuations.
Labour,
therefore, it appears evidently, is the only universal, as well
as the only accurate measure of value, or the only standard
by which we can compare the values of different commodities
at all times, and at all places. We cannot estimate, it is allowed,
the real value of different commodities from century to century
by the quantities of silver which were given for them. We cannot
estimate it from year to year by the quantities of corn. By
the quantities of labour we can, with the greatest accuracy,
estimate it both from century to century and from year to year.
From century to century, corn is a better measure than silver,
because, from century to century, equal quantities of corn will
command the same quantity of labour more nearly than equal quantities
of silver. From year to year, on the contrary, silver is a better
measure than corn, because equal quantities of it will more
nearly command the same quantity of labour.
But
though in establishing perpetual rents, or even in letting very
long leases, it may be of use to distinguish between real and
nominal price; it is of none in buying and selling, the more
common and ordinary transactions of human life.
At
the same time and place the real and the nominal price of all
commodities are exactly in proportion to one another. The more
or less money you get for any commodity, in the London market
for example, the more or less labour it will at that time and
place enable you to purchase or command. At the same time and
place, therefore, money is the exact measure of the real exchangeable
value of all commodities. It is so, however, at the same time
and place only.
Though
at distant places, there is no regular proportion between the
real and the money price of commodities, yet the merchant who
carries goods from the one to the other has nothing to consider
but their money price, or the difference between the quantity
of silver for which he buys them, and that for which he is likely
to sell them. Half an ounce of silver at Canton in China may
command a greater quantity both of labour and of the necessaries
and conveniences of life than an ounce at London. A commodity,
therefore, which sells for half an ounce of silver at Canton
may there be really dearer, of more real importance to the man
who possesses it there, than a commodity which sells for an
ounce at London is to the man who possesses it at London. If
a London merchant, however, can buy at Canton for half an ounce
of silver, a commodity which he can afterwards sell at London
for an ounce, he gains a hundred per cent by the bargain, just
as much as if an ounce of silver was at London exactly of the
same value as at Canton. It is of no importance to him that
half an ounce of silver at Canton would have given him the command
of more labour and of a greater quantity of the necessaries
and conveniences of life than an ounce can do at London. An
ounce at London will always give him the command of double the
quantity of all these which half an ounce could have done there,
and this is precisely what he wants.
As
it is the nominal or money price of goods, therefore, which
finally determines the prudence or imprudence of all purchases
and sales, and thereby regulates almost the whole business of
common life in which price is concerned, we cannot wonder that
it should have been so much more attended to than the real price.
In
such a work as this, however, it may sometimes be of use to
compare the different real values of a particular commodity
at different times and places, or the different degrees of power
over the labour of other people which it may, upon different
occasions, have given to those who possessed it. We must in
this case compare, not so much the different quantities of silver
for which it was commonly sold, as the different quantities
of labour which those different quantities of silver could have
purchased. But the current prices of labour at distant times
and places can scarce ever be known with any degree of exactness.
Those of corn, though they have in few places been regularly
recorded, are in general better known and have been more frequently
taken notice of by historians and other writers. We must generally,
therefore, content ourselves with them, not as being always
exactly in the same proportion as the current prices of labour,
but as being the nearest approximation which can commonly be
had to that proportion. I shall hereafter have occasion to make
several comparisons of this kind.
In
the progress of industry, commercial nations have found it convenient
to coin several different metals into money; gold for larger
payments, silver for purchases of moderate value, and copper,
or some other coarse metal, for those of still smaller consideration.
They have always, however, considered one of those metals as
more peculiarly the measure of value than any of the other two;
and this preference seems generally to have been given to the
metal which they happened first to make use of as the instrument
of commerce. Having once begun to use it as their standard,
which they must have done when they had no other money, they
have generally continued to do so even when the necessity was
not the same.
The
Romans are said to have had nothing but copper money till within
five years before the first Punic war, when they first began
to coin silver. Copper, therefore, appears to have continued
always the measure of value in that republic. At Rome all accounts
appear to have been kept, and the value of all estates to have
been computed either in asses or in sestertii. The as was always
the denomination of a copper coin. The word sestertius signifies
two asses and a half. Though the sestertius, therefore, was
originally a silver coin, its value was estimated in copper.
At Rome, one who owed a great deal of money was said to have
a great deal of other people's copper.
The
northern nations who established themselves upon the ruins of
the Roman empire, seem to have had silver money from the first
beginning of their settlements, and not to have known either
gold or copper coins for several ages thereafter. There were
silver coins in England in the time of the Saxons; but there
was little gold coined till the time of Edward III nor any copper
till that of James I of Great Britain. In England, therefore,
and for the same reason, I believe, in all other modern nations
of Europe, all accounts are kept, and the value of all goods
and of all estates is generally computed in silver: and when
we mean to express the amount of a person's fortune, we seldom
mention the number of guineas, but the number of pounds sterling
which we suppose would be given for it.
Originally,
in all countries, I believe, a legal tender of payment could
be made only in the coin of that metal, which was peculiarly
considered as the standard or measure of value. In England,
gold was not considered as a legal tender for a long time after
it was coined into money. The proportion between the values
of gold and silver money was not fixed by any public law or
proclamation; but was left to be settled by the market. If a
debtor offered payment in gold, the creditor might either reject
such payment altogether, or accept of it at such a valuation
of the gold as he and his debtor could agree upon. Copper is
not at present a legal tender except in the change of the smaller
silver coins. In this state of things the distinction between
the metal which was the standard, and that which was not the
standard, was something more than a nominal distinction.
In
process of time, and as people became gradually more familiar
with the use of the different metals in coin, and consequently
better acquainted with the proportion between their respective
values, it has in most countries, I believe, been found convenient
to ascertain this proportion, and to declare by a public law
that a guinea, for example, of such a weight and fineness, should
exchange for one-and-twenty shillings, or be a legal tender
for a debt of that amount. In this state of things, and during
the continuance of any one regulated proportion of this kind,
the distinction between the metal which is the standard, and
that which is not the standard, becomes little more than a nominal
distinction.
In
consequence of any change, however, in this regulated proportion,
this distinction becomes, or at least seems to become, something
more than nominal again. If the regulated value of a guinea,
for example, was either reduced to twenty, or raised to two-and-twenty
shillings, all accounts being kept and almost all obligations
for debt being expressed in silver money, the greater part of
payments could in either case be made with the same quantity
of silver money as before; but would require very different
quantities of gold money; a greater in the one case, and a smaller
in the other. Silver would appear to be more invariable in its
value than gold. Silver would appear to measure the value of
gold, and gold would not appear to measure the value of silver.
The value of gold would seem to depend upon the quantity of
silver which it would exchange for; and the value of silver
would not seem to depend upon the quantity of gold which it
would exchange for. This difference, however, would be altogether
owing to the custom of keeping accounts, and of expressing the
amount of all great and small sums rather in silver than in
gold money. One of Mr. Drummond's notes for five-and-twenty
or fifty guineas would, after an alteration of this kind, be
still payable with five-and-twenty or fifty guineas in the same
manner as before. It would, after such an alteration, be payable
with the same quantity of gold as before, but with very different
quantities of silver. In the payment of such a note, gold would
appear to be more invariable in its value than silver. Gold
would appear to measure the value of silver, and silver would
not appear to measure the value of gold. If the custom of keeping
accounts, and of expressing promissory notes and other obligations
for money in this manner, should ever become general, gold,
and not silver, would be considered as the metal which was peculiarly
the standard or measure of value.
In
reality, during the continuance of any one regulated proportion
between the respective values of the different metals in coin,
the value of the most precious metal regulates the value of
the whole coin. Twelve copper pence contain half a pound, avoirdupois,
of copper, of not the best quality, which, before it is coined,
is seldom worth sevenpence in silver. But as by the regulation
twelve such pence are ordered to exchange for a shilling, they
are in the market considered as worth a shilling, and a shilling
can at any time be had for them. Even before the late reformation
of the gold coin of Great Britain, the gold, that part of it
at least which circulated in London and its neighbourhood, was
in general less degraded below its standard weight than the
greater part of the silver. One-and-twenty worn and defaced
shillings, however, were considered as equivalent to a guinea,
which perhaps, indeed, was worn and defaced too, but seldom
so much so. The late regulations have brought the gold coin
as near perhaps to its standard weight as it is possible to
bring the current coin of any nation; and the order, to receive
no gold at the public offices but by weight, is likely to preserve
it so, as long as that order is enforced. The silver coin still
continues in the same worn and degraded state as before the
reformation of the gold coin. In the market, however, one-and-twenty
shillings of this degraded silver coin are still considered
as worth a guinea of this excellent gold coin.
The
reformation of the gold coin has evidently raised the value
of the silver coin which can be exchanged for it.
In
the English mint a pound weight of gold is coined into forty-four
guineas and a half, which, at one-and-twenty shillings the guinea,
is equal to forty-six pounds fourteen shillings and sixpence.
An ounce of such gold coin, therefore, is worth L3 17s. 10 1/2d.
in silver. In England no duty or seignorage is paid upon the
coinage, and he who carries a pound weight or an ounce weight
of standard gold bullion to the mint, gets back a pound weight
or an ounce weight of gold in coin, without any deduction. Three
pounds seventeen shillings and tenpence halfpenny an ounce,
therefore, is said to be the mint price of gold in England,
or the quantity of gold coin which the mint gives in return
for standard gold bullion.
Before
the reformation of the gold coin, the price of standard gold
bullion in the market had for many years been upwards of L3
18s. sometimes L3 19s. and very frequently L4 an ounce; that
sum, it is probable, in the worn and degraded gold coin, seldom
containing more than an ounce of standard gold. Since the reformation
of the gold coin, the market price of standard gold bullion
seldom exceeds L3 17s. 7d. an ounce. Before the reformation
of the gold coin, the market price was always more or less above
the mint price. Since that reformation, the market price has
been constantly below the mint price. But that market price
is the same whether it is paid in gold or in silver coin. The
late reformation of the gold coin, therefore, has raised not
only the value of the gold coin, but likewise that of the silver
coin in proportion to gold bullion, and probably, too, in proportion
to all other commodities; through the price of the greater part
of other commodities being influenced by so many other causes,
the rise in the value either of gold or silver coin in proportion
to them may not be so distinct and sensible.
In
the English mint a pound weight of standard silver bullion is
coined into sixty-two shillings, containing, in the same manner,
a pound weight of standard silver. Five shillings and twopence
an ounce, therefore, is said to be the mint price of silver
in England, or the quantity of silver coin which the mint gives
in return for standard silver bullion. Before the reformation
of the gold coin, the market price of standard silver bullion
was, upon different occasions, five shillings and fourpence,
five shillings and fivepence, five shillings and sixpence, five
shillings and sevenpence, and very often five shillings and
eightpence an ounce. Five shillings and sevenpence, however,
seems to have been the most common price. Since the reformation
of the gold coin, the market price of standard silver bullion
has fallen occasionally to five shillings and threepence, five
shillings and fourpence, and five shillings and fivepence an
ounce, which last price it has scarce ever exceeded. Though
the market price of silver bullion has fallen considerably since
the reformation of the gold coin, it has not fallen so low as
the mint price.
In
the proportion between the different metals in the English coin,
as copper is rated very much above its real value, so silver
is rated somewhat below it. In the market of Europe, in the
French coin and in the Dutch coin, an ounce of fine gold exchanges
for about fourteen ounces of fine silver. In the English coin,
it exchanges for about fifteen ounces, that is, for more silver
than it is worth according to the common estimation of Europe.
But as the price of copper in bars is not, even in England,
raised by the high price of copper in English coin, so the price
of silver in bullion is not sunk by the low rate of silver in
English coin. Silver in bullion still preserves its proper proportion
to gold; for the same reason that copper in bars preserves its
proper proportion to silver.
Upon
the reformation of the silver coin in the reign of William III
the price of silver bullion still continued to be somewhat above
the mint price. Mr. Locke imputed this high price to the permission
of exporting silver bullion, and to the prohibition of exporting
silver coin. This permission of exporting, he said, rendered
the demand for silver bullion greater than the demand for silver
coin. But the number of people who want silver coin for the
common uses of buying and selling at home, is surely much greater
than that of those who want silver bullion either for the use
of exportation or for any other use. There subsists at present
a like permission of exporting gold bullion, and a like prohibition
of exporting gold coin: and yet the price of gold bullion has
fallen below the mint price. But in the English coin silver
was then, in the same manner as now, under-rated in proportion
to gold, and the gold coin (which at that time too was not supposed
to require any reformation) regulated then, as well as now,
the real value of the whole coin. As the reformation of the
silver coin did not then reduce the price of silver bullion
to the mint price, it is not very probable that a like reformation
will do so now.
Were
the silver coin brought back as near to its standard weight
as the gold, a guinea, it is probable, would, according to the
present proportion, exchange for more silver in coin than it
would purchase in bullion. The silver coin containing its full
standard weight, there would in this case be a profit in melting
it down, in order, first, to sell the bullion for gold coin,
and afterwards to exchange this gold coin for silver coin to
be melted down in the same manner. Some alteration in the present
proportion seems to be the only method of preventing this inconveniency.
The
inconveniency perhaps would be less if silver was rated in the
coin as much above its proper proportion to gold as it is at
present rated below it; provided it was at the same time enacted
that silver should not be a legal tender for more than the change
of a guinea, in the same manner as copper is not a legal tender
for more than the change of a shilling. No creditor could in
this case be cheated in consequence of the high valuation of
silver in coin; as no creditor can at present be cheated in
consequence of the high valuation of copper. The bankers only
would suffer by this regulation. When a run comes upon them
they sometimes endeavour to gain time by paying in sixpences,
and they would be precluded by this regulation from this discreditable
method of evading immediate payment. They would be obliged in
consequence to keep at all times in their coffers a greater
quantity of cash than at present; and though this might no doubt
be a considerable inconveniency to them, it would at the same
time be a considerable security to their creditors.
Three
pounds seventeen shillings and tenpence halfpenny (the mint
price of gold) certainly does not contain, even in our present
excellent gold coin, more than an ounce of standard gold, and
it may be thought, therefore, should not purchase more standard
bullion. But gold in coin is more convenient than gold in bullion,
and though, in England, the coinage is free, yet the gold which
is carried in bullion to the mint can seldom be returned in
coin to the owner till after a delay of several weeks. In the
present hurry of the mint, it could not be returned till after
a delay of several months. This delay is equivalent to a small
duty, and renders gold in coin somewhat more valuable than an
equal quantity of gold in bullion. If in the English coin silver
was rated according to it proper proportion to gold, the price
of silver bullion would probably fall below the mint price even
without any reformation of the silver coin; the value even of
the present worn and defaced silver coin being regulated by
the value of the excellent gold coin for which it can be changed.
A
small seignorage or duty upon the coinage of both gold and silver
would probably increase still more the superiority of those
metals in coin above an equal quantity of either of them in
bullion. The coinage would in this case increase the value of
the metal coined in proportion to the extent of this small duty;
for the same reason that the fashion increases the value of
plate in proportion to the price of that fashion. The superiority
of coin above bullion would prevent the melting down of the
coin, and would discourage its exportation. If upon any public
exigency it should become necessary to export the coin, the
greater part of it would soon return again of its own accord.
Abroad it could sell only for its weight in bullion. At home
it would buy more than that weight. There would be a profit,
therefore, in bringing it home again. In France a seignorage
of about eight per cent is imposed upon the coinage, and the
French coin, when exported, is said to return home again of
its own accord.
The
occasional fluctuations in the market price of gold and silver
bullion arise from the same causes as the like fluctuations
in that of all other commodities. The frequent loss of those
metals from various accidents by sea and by land, the continual
waste of them in gilding and plating, in lace and embroidery,
in the wear and tear of coin, and in that of plate; require,
in all countries which possess no mines of their own, a continual
importation, in order to repair this loss and this waste. The
merchant importers, like all other merchants, we may believe,
endeavour, as well as they can, to suit their occasional importations
to what, they judge, is likely to be the immediate demand. With
all their attention, however, they sometimes overdo the business,
and sometimes underdo it. When they import more bullion than
is wanted, rather than incur the risk and trouble of exporting
it again, they are sometimes willing to sell a part of it for
something less than the ordinary or average price. When, on
the other hand, they import less than is wanted, they get something
more than this price. But when, under all those occasional fluctuations,
the market price either of gold or silver bullion continues
for several years together steadily and constantly, either more
or less above, or more or less below the mint price, we may
be assured that this steady and constant, either superiority
or inferiority of price, is the effect of something in the state
of the coin, which, at that time, renders a certain quantity
of coin either of more value or of less value than the precise
quantity of bullion which it ought to contain. The constancy
and steadiness of the effect supposes a proportionable constancy
and steadiness in the cause.
The
money of any particular country is, at any particular time and
place, more or less an accurate measure of value according as
the current coin is more or less exactly agreeable to its standard,
or contains more or less exactly the precise quantity of pure
gold or pure silver which it ought to contain. If in England,
for example, forty-four guineas and a half contained exactly
a pound weight of standard gold, or eleven ounces of fine gold
and one ounce of alloy, the gold coin of England would be as
accurate a measure of the actual value of goods at any particular
time and place as the nature of the thing would admit. But if,
by rubbing and wearing, forty-four guineas and a half generally
contain less than a pound weight of standard gold; the diminution,
however, being greater in some pieces than in others; the measure
of value comes to be liable to the same sort of uncertainty
to which all other weights and measures are commonly exposed.
As it rarely happens that these are exactly agreeable to their
standard, the merchant adjusts the price of his goods, as well
as he can, not to what those weights and measures ought to be,
but to what, upon an average, he finds by experience they actually
are. In consequence of a like disorder in the coin, the price
of goods comes, in the same manner, to be adjusted, not to the
quantity of pure gold or silver which the corn ought to contain,
but to that which, upon an average, it is found by experience,
it actually does contain.
By
the money-price of goods, it is to be observed, I understand
always the quantity of pure gold or silver for which they are
sold, without any regard to the denomination of the coin. Six
shillings and eightpence, for example, in the time of Edward
I, I consider as the same money-price with a pound sterling
in the present times; because it contained, as nearly as we
can judge, the same quantity of pure silver.
...
..
..