Of the Component Parts of
the Price of Commodities
In that
early and rude state of society which precedes both the accumulation
of stock and the appropriation of land, the proportion between
the quantities of labour necessary for acquiring different
objects seems to be the only circumstance which can afford
any rule for exchanging them for one another. If among a nation
of hunters, for example, it usually costs twice the labour
to kill a beaver which it does to kill a deer, one beaver
should naturally exchange for or be worth two deer. It is
natural that what is usually the produce of two days' or two
hours' labour, should be worth double of what is usually the
produce of one day's or one hour's labour.
If the
one species of labour should be more severe than the other,
some allowance will naturally be made for this superior hardship;
and the produce of one hour's labour in the one way may frequently
exchange for that of two hours' labour in the other.
Or if
the one species of labour requires an uncommon degree of dexterity
and ingenuity, the esteem which men have for such talents
will naturally give a value to their produce, superior to
what would be due to the time employed about it. Such talents
can seldom be acquired but in consequence of long application,
and the superior value of their produce may frequently be
no more than a reasonable compensation for the time and labour
which must be spent in acquiring them. In the advanced state
of society, allowances of this kind, for superior hardship
and superior skill, are commonly made in the wages of labour;
and something of the same kind must probably have taken place
in its earliest and rudest period.
In this
state of things, the whole produce of labour belongs to the
labourer; and the quantity of labour commonly employed in
acquiring or producing any commodity is the only circumstance
which can regulate the quantity exchange for which it ought
commonly to purchase, command, or exchange for.
As soon
as stock has accumulated in the hands of particular persons,
some of them will naturally employ it in setting to work industrious
people, whom they will supply with materials and subsistence,
in order to make a profit by the sale of their work, or by
what their labour adds to the value of the materials. In exchanging
the complete manufacture either for money, for labour, or
for other goods, over and above what may be sufficient to
pay the price of the materials, and the wages of the workmen,
something must be given for the profits of the undertaker
of the work who hazards his stock in this adventure. The value
which the workmen add to the materials, therefore, resolves
itself in this ease into two parts, of which the one pays
their wages, the other the profits of their employer upon
the whole stock of materials and wages which he advanced.
He could have no interest to employ them, unless he expected
from the sale of their work something more than what was sufficient
to replace his stock to him; and he could have no interest
to employ a great stock rather than a small one, unless his
profits were to bear some proportion to the extent of his
stock.
The profits
of stock, it may perhaps be thought are only a different name
for the wages of a particular sort of labour, the labour of
inspection and direction. They are, however, altogether different,
are regulated by quite different principles, and bear no proportion
to the quantity, the hardship, or the ingenuity of this supposed
labour of inspection and direction. They are regulated altogether
by the value of the stock employed, and are greater or smaller
in proportion to the extent of this stock. Let us suppose,
for example, that in some particular place, where the common
annual profits of manufacturing stock are ten per cent, there
are two different manufactures, in each of which twenty workmen
are employed at the rate of fifteen pounds a year each, or
at the expense of three hundred a year in each manufactory.
Let us suppose, too, that the coarse materials annually wrought
up in the one cost only seven hundred pounds, while the finer
materials in the other cost seven thousand. The capital annually
employed in the one will in this case amount only to one thousand
pounds; whereas that employed in the other will amount to
seven thousand three hundred pounds. At the rate of ten per
cent, therefore, the undertaker of the one will expect a yearly
profit of about one hundred pounds only; while that of the
other will expect about seven hundred and thirty pounds. But
though their profits are so very different, their labour of
inspection and direction may be either altogether or very
nearly the same. In many great works almost the whole labour
of this kind is committed to some principal clerk. His wages
properly express the value of this labour of inspection and
direction. Though in settling them some regard is had commonly,
not only to his labour and skill, but to the trust which is
reposed in him, yet they never bear any regular proportion
to the capital of which he oversees the management; and the
owner of this capital, though he is thus discharged of almost
all labour, still expects that his profits should bear a regular
proportion to his capital. In the price of commodities, therefore,
the profits of stock constitute a component part altmust be
due for the profits of the stock which advanced the wages
and furnished the materials of that labour.
As soon
as the land of any country has all become private property,
the landlords, like all other men, love to reap where they
never sowed, and demand a rent even for its natural produce.
The wood of the forest, the grass of the field, and all the
natural fruits of the earth, which, when land was in common,
cost the labourer only the trouble of gathering them, come,
even to him, to have an additional price fixed upon them.
He must then pay for the licence to gather them; and must
give up to the landlord a portion of what his labour either
collects or produces. This portion, or, what comes to the
same thing, the price of this portion, constitutes the rent
of land, and in the price of the greater part of commodities
makes a third component part.
The real
value of all the different component parts of price, it must
be observed, is measured by the quantity of labour which they
can, each of them, purchase or command. Labour measures the
value not only of that part of price which resolves itself
into labour, but of that which resolves itself into rent,
and of that which resolves itself into profit.
In every
society the price of every commodity finally resolves itself
into some one or other, or all of those three parts; and in
every improved society, all the three enter more or less,
as component parts, into the price of the far greater part
of commodities.
In the
price of corn, for example, one part pays the rent of the
landlord, another pays the wages or maintenance of the labourers
and labouring cattle employed in producing it, and the third
pays the profit of the farmer. These three parts seem either
immediately or ultimately to make up the whole price of corn.
A fourth part, it may perhaps be thought, is necessary for
replacing the stock of the farmer, or for compensating the
wear and tear of his labouring cattle, and other instruments
of husbandry. But it must be considered that the price of
any instrument of husbandry, such as a labouring horse, is
itself made up of the same three parts; the rent of the land
upon which he is reared, the labour of tending and rearing
him, and the profits of the farmer who advances both the rent
of this land, and the wages of this labour. Though the price
of the corn, therefore, may pay the price as well as the maintenance
of the horse, the whole price still resolves itself either
immediately or ultimately into the same three parts of rent,
labour, and profit.
In the
price of flour or meal, we must add to the price of the corn,
the profits of the miller, and the wages of his servants;
in the price of bread, the profits of the baker, and the wages
of his servants; and in the price of both, the labour of transporting
the corn from the house of the farmer to that of the miller,
and from that of the miner to that of the baker, together
with the profits of those who advance the wages of that labour.
The price
of flax resolves itself into the same three parts as that
of corn. In the price of linen we must add to this price the
wages of the flaxdresser, of the spinner, of the weaver, of
the bleacher, etc., together with the profits of their respective
employers.
As any
particular commodity comes to be more manufactured, that part
of the price which resolves itself into wages and profit comes
to be greater in proportion to that which resolves itself
into rent. In the progress of the manufacture, not only the
number of profits increase, but every subsequent profit is
greater than the foregoing; because the capital from which
it is derived must always be greater. The capital which employs
the weavers, for example, must be greater than that which
employs the spinners; because it not only replaces that capital
with its profits, but pays, besides, the wages of the weavers;
and the profits must always bear some proportion to the capital.
In the
most improved societies, however, there are always a few commodities
of which the price resolves itself into two parts only, the
wages of labour, and the profits of stock; and a still smaller
number, in which it consists altogether in the wages of labour.
In the price of sea-fish, for example, one part pays the labour
of the fishermen, and the other the profits of the capital
employed in the fishery. Rent very seldom makes any part of
it, though it does sometimes, as I shall show hereafter. It
is otherwise, at least through the greater part of Europe,
in river fisheries. A salmon fishery pays a rent, and rent,
though it cannot well be called the rent of land, makes a
part of the price of a salmon as well as wages and profit.
In some parts of Scotland a few poor people make a trade of
gathering, along the sea-shore, those little variegated stones
commonly known by the name of Scotch Pebbles. The price which
is paid to them by the stone-cutter is altogether the wages
of their labour; neither rent nor profit make any part of
it.
But the
whole price of any commodity must still finally resolve itself
into some one or other, or all of those three parts; as whatever
part of it remains after paying the rent of the land, and
the price of the whole labour employed in raising, manufacturing,
and bringing it to market, must necessarily be profit to somebody.
As the
price or exchangeable value of every particular commodity,
taken separately, resolves itself into some one or other or
all of those three parts; so that of all the commodities which
compose the whole annual produce of the labour of every country,
taken complexly, must resolve itself into the same three parts,
and be parcelled out among different inhabitants of the country,
either as the wages of their labour, the profits of their
stock, or the rent of their land. The whole of what is annually
either collected or produced by the labour of every society,
or what comes to the same thing, the whole price of it, is
in this manner originally distributed among some of its different
members. Wages, profit, and rent, are the three original sources
of all revenue as well as of all exchangeable value. All other
revenue is ultimately derived from some one or other of these.
Whoever
derives his revenue from a fund which is his own, must draw
it either from his labour, from his stock, or from his land.
The revenue derived from labour is called wages. That derived
from stock, by the person who manages or employes it, is called
profit. That derived from it by the person who does not employ
it himself, but lends it to another, is called the interest
or the use of money. It is the compensation which the borrower
pays to the lender, for the profit which he has an opportunity
of making by the use of the money. Part of that profit naturally
belongs to the borrower, who runs the risk and takes the trouble
of employing it; and part to the lender, who affords him the
opportunity of making this profit. The interest of money is
always a derivative revenue, which, if it is not paid from
the profit which is made by the use of the money, must be
paid from some other source of revenue, unless perhaps the
borrower is a spendthrift, who contracts a second debt in
order to pay the interest of the first. The revenue which
proceeds altogether from land, is called rent, and belongs
to the landlord. The revenue of the farmer is derived partly
from his labour, and partly from his stock. To him, land is
only the instrument which enables him to earn the wages of
this labour, and to make the profits of this stock. All taxes,
and an the revenue which is founded upon them, all salaries,
pensions, and annuities of every kind, are ultimately derived
from some one or other of those three original sources of
revenue, and are paid either immediately or mediately from
the wages of labour, the profits of stock, or the rent of
land.
When
those three different sorts of revenue belong to different
persons, they are readily distinguished; but when they belong
to the same they are sometimes confounded with one another,
at least in common language.
A gentleman
who farms a part of his own estate, after paying the expense
of cultivation, should gain both the rent of the landlord
and the profit of the farmer. He is apt to denominate, however,
his whole gain, profit, and thus confounds rent with profit,
at least in common language. The greater part of our North
American and West Indian planters are in this situation. They
farm, the greater part of them, their own estates, and accordingly
we seldom hear of the rent of a plantation, but frequently
of its profit.
Common
farmers seldom employ any overseer to direct the general operations
of the farm. They generally, too, work a good deal with their
own hands, as ploughmen, harrowers, etc. What remains of the
crop after paying the rent, therefore, should not only replace
to them their stock employed in cultivation, together with
its ordinary profits, but pay them the wages which are due
to them, both as labourers and overseers. Whatever remains,
however, after paying the rent and keeping up the stock, is
called profit. But wages evidently make a part of it. The
farmer, by saving these wages, must necessarily gain them.
Wages, therefore, are in this case confounded with profit.
An independent
manufacturer, who has stock enough both to purchase materials,
and to maintain himself till he can carry his work to market,
should gain both the wages of a journeyman who works under
a master, and the profit which that master makes by the sale
of the journeyman's work. His whole gains, however, are commonly
called profit, and wages are, in this case too, confounded
with profit.
A gardener
who cultivates his own garden with his own hands, unites in
his own person the three different characters of landlord,
farmer, and labourer. His produce, therefore, should pay him
the rent of the first, the profit of the second, and the wages
of the third. The whole, however, is commonly considered as
the earnings of his labour. Both rent and profit are, in this
case, confounded with wages.
As in
a civilised country there are but few commodities of which
the exchangeable value arises from labour only, rent and profit
contributing largely to that of the far greater part of them,
so the annual produce of its labour will always be sufficient
to purchase or command a much greater quantity of labour than
what employed in raising, preparing, and bringing that produce
to market. If the society were annually to employ all the
labour which it can annually purchase, as the quantity of
labour would increase greatly every year, so the produce of
every succeeding year would be of vastly greater value than
that of the foregoing. But there is no country in which the
whole annual produce is employed in maintaining the industrious.
The idle everywhere consume a great part of it; and according
to the different proportions in which it is annually divided
between those two different orders of people, its ordinary
or average value must either annually increase, or diminish,
or continue the same from one year to another.