The labour of some of the most respectable orders in the society is, like
that of menial servants, unproductive of any value, and does not fix or realize
itself in any permanent subject; or vendible commodity, which endures after
that labour is past, and for which an equal quantity of labour could afterwards
be procured. The sovereign, for example, with all the officers both of justice
and war who serve under him, the whole army and navy, are unproductive labourers.
They are the servants of the public, and are maintained by a part of the
annual produce of the industry of other people. Their service, how honourable,
how useful, or how necessary soever, produces nothing for which an equal
quantity of service can afterwards be procured. The protection, security,
and defence of the commonwealth, the effect of their labour this year will
not purchase its protection, security, and defence for the year to come.
In the same class must be ranked, some both of the gravest and most important,
and some of the most frivolous professions: churchmen, lawyers, physicians,
men of letters of all kinds; players, buffoons, musicians, opera-singers,
opera-dancers, etc. The labour of the meanest of these has a certain value,
regulated by the very same principles which regulate that of every other
sort of labour; and that of the n oblest and most useful, 50 produces nothing
which could afterwards purchase or procure an equal quantity of labour. Like
the declamation of the actor, the harangue of the orator, or the tune of
the musician, the work of all of them perishes in the very instant of its
production.
Both productive and unproductive labourers, and those who do not labour
at all, are all equally maintained by the annual produce of the land and
labour of the country. This produce, how great soever, can never be infinite,
but must have certain limits. According, therefore, as a smaller or greater
proportion of it is in any one year employed in maintaining unproductive
hands, the more in the one case and the less in the other will remain for
the productive, and the next year's produce will be greater or smaller accordingly;
the whole annual produce, if we except the spontaneous productions of the
earth, being the effect of productive labour.
Though the whole annual produce of the land and labour of every country
is, no doubt, ultimately destined for supplying the consumption of its inhabitants,
and for procuring a revenue to them, yet when it first comes either from
the ground, or from the hands of the productive labourers, it naturally divides
itself into two parts. One of them, and frequently the largest, is, in the
first place, destined for replacing a capital, or for renewing the provisions,
materials, and finished work, which had been withdrawn from a capital; the
other for constituting a revenue either to the owner of this capital, as
the profit of his stock, or to some other person, as the rent of his land.
Thus, of the produce of land, one part replaces the capital of the farmer;
the other pays his profit and the rent of the landlord; and thus constitutes
a revenue both to the owner of this capital, as the profits of his stock;
and to some other person, as the rent of his land. Of the produce of a great
manufactory, in the same manner, one part, and that always the largest, replaces
the capital of the undertaker of the work; the other pays his profit, and
thus constitutes a revenue to the owner of this capital.
That part of the annual produce of the land and labour of any country which
replaces a capital never is immediately employed to maintain any but productive
hands. It pays the wages of productive labour only. That which is immediately
destined for constituting a revenue, either as profit or as rent, may maintain
indifferently either productive or unproductive hands.
Whatever part of his stock a man employs as a capital, he always expects
is to be replaced to him with a profit. He employs it, therefore, in maintaining
productive bands only; and after having served in the function of a capital
to him, it constitutes a revenue to them. Whenever he employs any part of
it in maintaining unproductive hands of any kind, that part is, from that
moment, withdrawn from his capital, and placed in his stock reserved for
immediate consumption.
Unproductive labourers, and those who do not labour at all, are all maintained
by revenue; either, first, by that part of the annual produce which is originally
destined for constituting a revenue to some particular persons, either as
the rent of land or as the profits of stock; or, secondly, by that part which,
though originally destined for replacing a capital and for maintaining productive
labourers only, yet when it comes into their hands whatever part of it is
over and above their necessary subsistence may be employed in maintaining
indifferently either productive or unproductive hands. Thus, not only the
great landlord or the rich merchant, but even the common workman, if his
wages are considerable, may maintain a menial servant; or he may sometimes
go to a play or a puppetshow, and so contribute his share towards maintaining
one set of unproductive labourers; or he may pay some taxes, and thus help
to maintain another set, more honourable and useful indeed, but equally unproductive.
No part of the annual produce, however, which had been originally destined
to replace a capital, is ever directed towards maintaining unproductive hands
till after it has put into motion its full complement of productive labour,
or all that it could put into motion in the way in which it was employed.
The workman must have earned his wages by work done before he can employ
any part of them in this manner. That part, too, is generally but a small
one. It is his spare revenue only, of which productive labourers have seldom
a great deal. They generally have some, however; and in the payment of taxes
the greatness of their number may compensate, in some measure, the smallness
of their contribution. The rent of land and the profits of stock are everywhere,
therefore, the principal sources from which unproductive hands derive their
subsistence. These are the two sorts of revenue of which the owners have
generally most to spare. They might both maintain indifferently either productive
or unproductive hands. They seem, however, to have some predilection for
the latter. The expense of a great lord feeds generally more idle than industrious
people. The rich merchant, though with his capital he maintains industrious
people only, yet by his expense, that is, by the employment of his revenue,
he feeds commonly the very same sort as the great lord.
The proportion, therefore, between the productive and unproductive hands,
depends very much in every country upon the proportion between that part
of the annual produce, which, as soon as it comes either from the ground
or from the hands of the productive labourers, is destined for replacing
a capital, and that which is destined for constituting a revenue, either
as rent or as profit. This proportion is very different in rich from what
it is in poor countries.
Thus, at present, in the opulent countries of Europe, a very large, frequently
the largest portion of the produce of the land is destined for replacing
the capital of the rich and independent farmer; the other for paying his
profits and the rent of the landlord. But anciently, during the prevalency
of the feudal government, a very small portion of the produce was sufficient
to replace the capital employed in cultivation. It consisted commonly in
a few wretched cattle, maintained altogether by the spontaneous produce of
uncultivated land, and which might, therefore, be considered as a part of
that spontaneous produce. It generally, too, belonged to the landlord, and
was by him advanced to the occupiers of the land. All the rest of the produce
properly belonged to him too, either as rent for his land, or as profit upon
this paltry capital. The occupiers of land were generally bondmen, whose
persons and effects were equally his property. Those who were not bondmen
were tenants at will, and though the rent which they paid was often nominally
little more than a quit-rent, it really amounted to the whole produce of
the land. Their lord could at all times command their labour in peace and
their service in war. Though they lived at a distance from his house, they
were equally dependent upon him as his retainers who lived in it. But the
whole produce of the land undoubtedly belongs to him who can dispose of the
labour and service of all those whom it maintains. In the present state of
Europe, the share of the landlord seldom exceeds a third, sometimes not a
fourth part of the whole produce of the land. The rent of land, however,
in all the improved parts of the country, has been tripled and quadrupled
since those ancient times; and this third or fourth part of the annual produce
is, it seems, three or four times greater than the whole had been before.
In the progress of improvement, rent, though it increases in proportion to
the extent, diminishes in proportion to the produce of the land.
In the opulent countries of Europe, great capitals are at present employed
in trade and manufactures. In the ancient state, the little trade that was
stirring, and the few homely and coarse manufactures that were carried on,
required but very small capitals. These, however, must have yielded very
large profits. The rate of interest was nowhere less than ten per cent, and
their profits must have been sufficient to afford this great interest. At
present the rate of interest, in the improved parts of Europe, is nowhere
higher than six per cent, and in some of the most improved it is so low as
four, three, and two per cent. Though that part of the revenue of the inhabitants
which is derived from the profits of stock is always much greater in rich
than in poor countries, it is because the stock is much greater: in proportion
to the stock the profits are generally much less.
That part of the annual produce, therefore, which, as soon as it comes either
from the ground or from the hands of the productive labourers, is destined
for replacing a capital, is not only much greater in rich than in poor countries,
but bears a much greater proportion to that which is immediately destined
for constituting a revenue either as rent or as profit. The funds destined
for the maintenance of productive labour are not only much greater in the
former than in the latter, but bear a much greater proportion to those which,
though they may be employed to maintain either productive or unproductive
hands, have generally a predilection for the latter.
The proportion between those different funds necessarily determines in every
country the general character of the inhabitants as to industry or idleness.
We are more industrious than our forefathers; because in the present times
the funds destined for the maintenance of industry are much greater in
proportion to those which are likely to be employed in the maintenance of
idleness than
they were two or three centuries ago. Our ancestors were idle for want
of a sufficient encouragement to industry. It is better, says the proverb,
to
play for nothing than to work for nothing. In mercantile and manufacturing
towns, where the inferior ranks of people are chiefly maintained by the
employment of capital, they are in general industrious, sober, and thriving;
as in many
English, and in most Dutch towns. In those towns which are principally
supported by the constant or occasional residence of a court, and in which
the inferior
ranks of people are chiefly maintained by the spending of revenue, they
are in general idle, dissolute, and poor; as at Rome, Versailles, Compiegne,
and Fontainebleu. If you except Rouen and Bordeaux, there is little trade
or industry in any of the parliament towns of France; and the inferior
ranks
of people, being elderly maintained by the expense of the members of the
courts of justice, and of those who come to plead before them, are in general
idle and poor. The great trade of Rouen and Bordeaux seems to be altogether
the effect of their situation. Rouen is necessarily the entrepot of almost
all the goods which are brought either from foreign countries, or from
the maritime provinces of France, for the consumption of the great city of
Paris.
Bordeaux is in the same manner the entrepot of the wines which grow upon
the banks of the Garonne, and of the rivers which run into it, one of the
richest wine countries in the world, and which seems to produce the wine
fittest for exportation, or best suited to the taste of foreign nations.
Such advantageous situations necessarily attract a great capital by the
great employment which they afford it; and the employment of this capital
is the
cause of the industry of those two cities. In the other parliament towns
of France, very little more capital seems to be employed than what is necessary
for supplying their own consumption; that is, little more than the smallest
capital which can be employed in them. The same thing may be said of Paris,
Madrid, and Vienna. Of those three cities, Paris is by far the most industrious;
but Paris itself is the principal market of all the manufactures established
at Paris, and its own consumption is the principal object of all the trade
which it carries on. London, Lisbon, and Copenhagen, are, perhaps, the
only three cities in Europe which are both the constant residence of a court,
and can at the same time be considered as trading cities, or as cities
which
trade not only for their own consumption, but for that of other cities
and countries. The situation of all the three is extremely advantageous,
and
naturally fits them to be the entrepots of a great part of the goods destined
for the consumption of distant places. In a city where a great revenue
is spent, to employ with advantage a capital for any other purpose than for
supplying the consumption of that city is probably more difficult than
in
one in which the inferior ranks of people have no other maintenance but
what they derive from the employment of such a capital. The idleness of the
greater
part of the people who are maintained by the expense of revenue corrupts,
it is probable, the industry of those who ought to be maintained by the
employment of capital, and renders it less advantageous to employ a capital
there than
in other places. There was little trade or industry in Edinburgh before
the union. When the Scotch Parliament was no longer to be assembled in it,
when
it ceased to be the necessary residence of the principal nobility and gentry
of Scotland, it became a city of some trade and industry. It still continues,
however, to be the residence of the principal courts of justice in Scotland,
of the Boards of Customs and Excise, etc. A considerable revenue, therefore,
still continues to be spent in it. In trade and industry it is much inferior
to Glasgow, of which the inhabitants are chiefly maintained by the employment
of capital. The inhabitants of a large village, it has sometimes been observed,
after having made considerable progress in manufactures, have become idle
and poor in consequence of a great lord having taken up his residence in
their neighbourhood.
The proportion between capital and revenue, therefore, seems everywhere
to regulate the proportion between industry and idleness. Wherever capital
predominates, industry prevails: wherever revenue, idleness. Every increase
or diminution of capital, therefore, naturally tends to increase or diminish
the real quantity of industry, the number of productive hands, and consequently
the exchangeable value of the annual produce of the land and labour of the
country, the real wealth and revenue of all its inhabitants.
Capitals are increased by parsimony, and diminished by prodigality and misconduct.
Whatever a person saves from his revenue he adds to his capital, and either
employs it himself in maintaining an additional number of productive hands,
or enables some other person to do so, by lending it to him for an interest,
that is, for a share of the profits. As the capital of an individual can
be increased only by what he saves from his annual revenue or his annual
gains, so the capital of a society, which is the same with that of all the
individuals who compose it, can be increased only in the same manner.
Parsimony, and not industry, is the immediate cause of the increase of capital.
Industry, indeed, provides the subject which parsimony accumulates. But whatever
industry might acquire, if parsimony did not save and store up, the capital
would never be the greater.
Parsimony, by increasing the fund which is destined for the maintenance
of productive hands, tends to increase the number of those hands whose labour
adds to the value of the subject upon which it is bestowed. It tends, therefore,
to increase the exchangeable value of the annual produce of the land and
labour of the country. It puts into motion an additional quantity of industry,
which gives an additional value to the annual produce.
What is annually saved is as regularly consumed as what is annually spent,
and nearly in the same time too; but it is consumed by a different set of
people. That portion of his revenue which a rich man annually spends is in
most cases consumed by idle guests and menial servants, who leave nothing
behind them in return for their consumption. That portion which he annually
saves, as for the sake of the profit it is immediately employed as a capital,
is consumed in the same manner, and nearly in the same time too, but by a
different set of people, by labourers, manufacturers, and artificers, who
reproduce with a profit the value of their annual consumption. His revenue,
we shall suppose, is paid him in money. Had he spent the whole, the food,
clothing, and lodging, which the whole could have purchased, would have been
distributed among the former set of people. By saving a part of it, as that
part is for the sake of the profit immediately employed as a capital either
by himself or by some other person, the food, clothing, and lodging, which
may be purchased with it, are necessarily reserved for the latter. The consumption
is the same, but the consumers are different.
By what a frugal man annually saves, he not only affords maintenance to
an additional number of productive hands, for that or the ensuing year, but,
like the founder of a public workhouse, he establishes as it were a perpetual
fund for the maintenance of an equal number in all times to come. The perpetual
allotment and destination of this fund, indeed, is not always guarded by
any positive law, by any trust-right or deed of mortmain. It is always guarded,
however, by a very powerful principle, the plain and evident interest of
every individual to whom any share of it shall ever belong. No part of it
can ever afterwards be employed to maintain any but productive hands without
an evident loss to the person who thus perverts it from its proper destination.
The prodigal perverts it in this manner. By not confining his expense within
his income, he encroaches upon his capital. Like him who perverts the revenues
of some pious foundation to profane purposes, he pays the wages of idleness
with those funds which the frugality of his forefathers had, as it were,
consecrated to the maintenance of industry. By diminishing the funds destined
for the employment of productive labour, he necessarily diminishes, so far
as it depends upon him, the quantity of that labour which adds a value to
the subject upon which it is bestowed, and, consequently, the value of the
annual produce of the land and labour of the whole country, the real wealth
and revenue of its inhabitants. If the prodigality of some was not compensated
by the frugality of others, the conduct of every prodigal, by feeding the
idle with the bread of the industrious, tends not only to beggar himself,
but to impoverish his country.
Though the expense of the prodigal should be altogether in home-made, and
no part of it in foreign commodities, its effect upon the productive funds
of the society would still be the same. Every year there would still be a
certain quantity of food and clothing, which ought to have maintained productive,
employed in maintaining unproductive hands. Every year, therefore, there
would still be some diminution in what would otherwise have been the value
of the annual produce of the land and labour of the country.
This expense, it may be said indeed, not being in foreign goods, and not
occasioning any exportation of gold and silver, the same quantity of money
would remain in the country as before. But if the quantity of food and clothing,
which were thus consumed by unproductive, had been distributed among productive
hands, they would have reproduced, together with a profit, the full value
of their consumption. The same quantity of money would in this case equally
have remained in the country, and there would besides have been a reproduction
of an equal value of consumable goods. There would have been two values instead
of one.
The same quantity of money, besides, cannot long remain in any country in
which the value of the annual produce diminishes. The sole use of money is
to circulate consumable goods. By means of it, provisions, materials, and
finished work, are bought and sold, and distributed to their proper consumers.
The quantity of money, therefore, which can be annually employed in any country
must be determined by the value of the consumable goods annually circulated
within it. These must consist either in the immediate produce of the land
and labour of the country itself, or in something which had been, purchased
with some part of that produce. Their value, therefore, must diminish as
the value of that produce diminishes, and along with it the quantity of money
which can be employed in circulating them. But the money which by this annual
diminution of produce is annually thrown out of domestic circulation will
not be allowed to lie idle. The interest of whoever possesses it requires
that it should be employed. But having no employment at home, it will, in
spite of all laws and prohibitions, be sent abroad, and employed in purchasing
consumable goods which may be of some use at home. Its annual exportation
will in this manner continue for some time to add something to the annual
consumption of the country beyond the value of its own annual produce. What
in the days of its prosperity had been saved from that annual produce, and
employed in purchasing gold and silver, will contribute for some little time
to support its consumption in adversity. The exportation of gold and silver
is, in this case, not the cause, but the effect of its declension, and may
even, for some little time, alleviate the misery of that declension.
The quantity of money, on the contrary, must in every country naturally
increase as the value of the annual produce increases. The value of the consumable
goods annually circulated within the society being greater will require a
greater quantity of money to circulate them. A part of the increased produce,
therefore, will naturally be employed in purchasing, wherever it is to be
had, the additional quantity of gold and silver necessary for circulating
the rest. The increase of those metals will in this case be the effect, not
the cause, of the public prosperity. Gold and silver are purchased everywhere
in the same manner. The food, clothing, and lodging, the revenue and maintenance
of all those whose labour or stock is employed in bringing them from the
mine to the market, is the price paid for them in Peru as well as in England.
The country which has this price to pay will never be long without the quantity
of those metals which it has occasion for; and no country will ever long
retain a quantity which it has no occasion for.
Whatever, therefore, we may imagine the real wealth and revenue of a country
to consist in, whether in the value of the annual produce of its land and
labour, as plain reason seems to dictate; or in the quantity of the precious
metals which circulate within it, as vulgar prejudices suppose; in either
view of the matter, every prodigal appears to be a public enemy, and every
frugal man a public benefactor.
The effects of misconduct are often the same as those of prodigality. Every
injudicious and unsuccessful project in agriculture, mines, fisheries, trade,
or manufactures, tends in the same manner to diminish the funds destined
for the maintenance of productive labour. In every such project, though the
capital is consumed by productive hands only, yet, as by the injudicious
manner in which they are employed they do not reproduce the full value of
their consumption, there must always be some diminution in what would otherwise
have been the productive funds of the society.
It can seldom happen, indeed, that the circumstances of a great nation can
be much affected either by the prodigality or misconduct of individuals;
the profusion or imprudence of some being always more than compensated by
the frugality and good conduct of others.
With regard to profusion, the principle which prompts to expense is the
passion for present enjoyment; which, though sometimes violent and very difficult
to be restrained, is in general only momentary and occasional. But the principle
which prompts to save is the desire of bettering our condition, a desire
which, though generally calm and dispassionate, comes with us from the womb,
and never leaves us till we go into the grave. In the whole interval which
separates those two moments, there is scarce perhaps a single instant in
which any man is so perfectly and completely satisfied with his situation
as to be without any wish of alteration or improvement of any kind. An augmentation
of fortune is the means by which the greater part of men propose and wish
to better their condition. It is the means the most vulgar and the most obvious;
and the most likely way of augmenting their fortune is to save and accumulate
some part of what they acquire, either regularly and annually, or upon some
extraordinary occasions. Though the principle of expense, therefore, prevails
in almost all men upon some occasions, and in some men upon almost all occasions,
yet in the greater part of men, taking the whole course of their life at
an average, the principle of frugality seems not only to predominate, but
to predominate very greatly.
With regard to misconduct, the number of prudent and successful undertakings
is everywhere much greater than that of injudicious and unsuccessful ones.
After all our complaints of the frequency of bankruptcies, the unhappy men
who fall into this misfortune make but a very small part of the whole number
engaged in trade, and all other sorts of business; not much more perhaps
than one in a thousand. Bankruptcy is perhaps the greatest and most humiliating
calamity which can befall an innocent man. The greater part of men, therefore,
are sufficiently careful to avoid it. Some, indeed, do not avoid it; as some
do not avoid the gallows.
Great nations are never impoverished by private, though they sometimes are
by public prodigality and misconduct. The whole, or almost the whole public
revenue, is in most countries employed in maintaining unproductive hands.
Such are the people who compose a numerous and splendid court, a great ecclesiastical
establishment, great fleets and armies, who in time of peace produce nothing,
and in time of war acquire nothing which can compensate the expense of maintaining
them, even while the war lasts. Such people, as they themselves produce nothing,
are all maintained by the produce of other men's labour. When multiplied,
therefore, to an unnecessary number, they may in a particular year consume
so great a share of this produce, as not to leave a sufficiency for maintaining
the productive labourers, who should reproduce it next year. The next year's
produce, therefore, will be less than that of the foregoing, and if the same
disorder should continue, that of the third year will be still less than
that of the second. Those unproductive hands, who should be maintained by
a part only of the spare revenue of the people, may consume so great a share
of their whole revenue, and thereby oblige so great a number to encroach
upon their capitals, upon the funds destined for the maintenance of productive
labour, that all the frugality and good conduct of individuals may not be
able to compensate the waste and degradation of produce occasioned by this
violent and forced encroachment.
This frugality and good conduct, however, is upon most occasions, it appears
from experience, sufficient to compensate, not only the private prodigality
and misconduct of individuals, but the public extravagance of government.
The uniform, constant, and uninterrupted effort of every man to better his
condition, the principle from which public and national, as well as private
opulence is originally derived, is frequently powerful enough to maintain
the natural progress of things towards improvement, in spite both of the
extravagance of government and of the greatest errors of administration.
Like the unknown principle of animal life, it frequently restores health
and vigour to the constitution, in spite, not only of the disease, but of
the absurd prescriptions of the doctor.
The annual produce of the land and labour of any nation can be increased
in its value by no other means but by increasing either the number of its
productive labourers, or the productive powers of those labourers who had
before been employed. The number of its productive labourers, it is evident,
can never be much increased, but in consequence of an increase of capital,
or of the funds destined for maintaining them. The productive powers of the
same number of labourers cannot be increased, but in consequence either of
some addition and improvement to those machines and instruments which facilitate
and abridge labour; or of a more proper division and distribution of employment.
In either case an additional capital is almost always required. It is by
means of an additional capital only that the undertaker of any work can either
provide his workmen with better machinery or make a more proper distribution
of employment among them. When the work to be done consists of a number of
parts, to keep every man constantly employed in one way requires a much greater
capital than where every man is occasionally employed in every different
part of the work. When we compare, therefore, the state of a nation at two
different periods, and find, that the annual produce of its land and labour
is evidently greater at the latter than at the former, that its lands are
better cultivated, its manufactures more numerous and more flourishing, and
its trade more extensive, we may be assured that its capital must have increased
during the interval between those two periods, and that more must have been
added to it by the good conduct of some than had been taken from it either
by the private misconduct of others or by the public extravagance of government.
But we shall find this to have been the case of almost all nations, in all
tolerably quiet and peaceable times, even of those who have not enjoyed the
most prudent and parsimonious governments. To form a right judgment of it,
indeed, we must compare the state of the country at periods somewhat distant
from one another. The progress is frequently so gradual that, at near periods,
the improvement is not only not sensible, but from the declension either
of certain branches of industry, or of certain districts of the country,
things which sometimes happen though the country in general be in great prosperity,
there frequently arises a suspicion that the riches and industry of the whole
are decaying.
The annual produce of the land and labour of England, for example, is certainly
much greater than it was, a little more than a century ago, at the restoration
of Charles II. Though, at present, few people, I believe, doubt of this,
yet during this period, five years have seldom passed away in which some
book or pamphlet has not been published, written, too, with such abilities
as to gain some authority with the public, and pretending to demonstrate
that the wealth of the nation was fast declining, that the country was depopulated,
agriculture neglected, manufactures decaying, and trade undone. Nor have
these publications been all party pamphlets, the wretched offspring of falsehood
and venality. Many of them have been written by very candid and very intelligent
people, who wrote nothing but what they believed, and for no other reason
but because they believed it.
The annual produce of the land and labour of England, again, was certainly
much greater at the Restoration, than we can suppose it to have been about
an hundred years before, at the accession of Elizabeth. At this period, too,
we have all reason to believe, the country was much more advanced in improvement
than it had been about a century before, towards the close of the dissensions
between the houses of York and Lancaster. Even then it was, probably, in
a better condition than it had been at the Norman Conquest, and at the Norman
Conquest than during the confusion of the Saxon Heptarchy. Even at this early
period, it was certainly a more improved country than at the invasion of
Julius Caesar, when its inhabitants were nearly in the same state with the
savages in North America.
In each of those periods, however, there was not only much private and public
profusion, many expensive and unnecessary wars, great perversion of the annual
produce from maintaining productive to maintain unproductive hands; but sometimes,
in the confusion of civil discord, such absolute waste and destruction of
stock, as might be supposed, not only to retard, as it certainly did, the
natural accumulation of riches, but to have left the country, at the end
of the period, poorer than at the beginning. Thus, in the happiest and most
fortunate period of them all, that which has passed since the Restoration,
how many disorders and misfortunes have occurred, which, could they have
been foreseen, not only the impoverishment, but the total ruin of the country
would have been expected from them? The fire and the plague of London, the
two Dutch wars, the disorders of the Revolution, the war in Ireland, the
four expensive French wars of 1688, 1702, 1742, and 1756, together with the
two rebellions of 1715 and 1745. In the course of the four French wars, the
nation has contracted more than a hundred and forty-five millions of debt,
over and above all the other extraordinary annual expense which they occasioned,
so that the whole cannot be computed at less than two hundred millions. So
great a share of the annual produce of the land and labour of the country
has, since the Revolution, been employed upon different occasions in maintaining
an extraordinary number of unproductive hands. But had not those wars given
this particular direction to so large a capital, the greater part of it would
naturally have been employed in maintaining productive hands, whose labour
would have replaced, with a profit, the whole value of their consumption.
The value of the annual produce of the land and labour of the country would
have been considerably increased by it every year, and every year's increase
would have augmented still more that of the following year. More houses would
have been built, more lands would have been improved, and those which had
been improved before would have been better cultivated, more manufactures
would have been established. and those which had been established before
would have been more extended; and to what height the real wealth and revenue
of the country might, by this time, have been raised, it is not perhaps very
easy even to imagine.
But though the profusion of government must, undoubtedly, have retarded
the natural progress of England towards wealth and improvement, it has not
been able to stop it. The annual produce of its land and labour is, undoubtedly,
much greater at present than it was either at the Restoration or at the Revolution.
The capital, therefore, annually employed in cultivating this land, and in
maintaining this labour, must likewise be much greater. In the midst of all
the exactions of government, this capital has been silently and gradually
accumulated by the private frugality and good conduct of individuals, by
their universal, continual, and uninterrupted effort to better their own
condition. It is this effort, protected by law and allowed by liberty to
exert itself in the manner that is most advantageous, which has maintained
the progress of England towards opulence and improvement in almost all former
times, and which, it is to be hoped, will do so in all future times. England,
however, as it has never been blessed with a very parsimonious government,
so parsimony has at no time been the characteristical virtue of its inhabitants.
It is the highest impertinence and presumption, therefore, in kings and ministers,
to pretend to watch over the economy of private people, and to restrain their
expense, either by sumptuary laws, or by prohibiting the importation of foreign
luxuries. They are themselves always, and without any exception, the greatest
spendthrifts in the society. Let them look well after their own expense,
and they may safely trust private people with theirs. If their own extravagance
does not ruin the state, that of their subjects never will.
As frugality increases and prodigality diminishes the public capital, so
the conduct of those whose expense just equals their revenue, without either
accumulating or encroaching, neither increases nor diminishes it. Some modes
of expense, however, seem to contribute more to the growth of public opulence
than others.
The revenue of an individual may be spent either in things which are consumed
immediately, and in which one day's expense can neither alleviate nor support
that of another, or it may be spent in things more durable, which can therefore
be accumulated, and in which every day's expense may, as he chooses, either
alleviate or support and heighten the effect of that of the following day.
A man of fortune, for example, may either spend his revenue in a profuse
and sumptuous table, and in maintaining a great number of menial servants,
and a multitude of dogs and horses; or contenting himself with a frugal table
and few attendants, he may lay out the greater part of it in adorning his
house or his country villa, in useful or ornamental buildings, in useful
or ornamental furniture, in collecting books, statues, pictures; or in things
more frivolous, jewels, baubles, ingenious trinkets of different kinds; or,
what is most trifling of all, in amassing a great wardrobe of fine clothes,
like the favourite and minister of a great prince who died a few years ago.
Were two men of equal fortune to spend their revenue, the one chiefly in
the one way, the other in the other, the magnificence of the person whose
expense had been chiefly in durable commodities, would be continually increasing,
every day's expense contributing something to support and heighten the effect
of that of the following day: that of the other, on the contrary, would be
no greater at the end of the period than at the beginning. The former, too,
would, at the end of the period, be the richer man of the two. He would have
a stock of goods of some kind or other, which, though it might not be worth
all that it cost, would always be worth something. No trace or vestige of
the expense of the latter would remain, and the effects of ten or twenty
years profusion would be as completely annihilated as if they had never existed.
As the one mode of expense is more favourable than the other to the opulence
of an individual, so is it likewise to that of a nation. The houses, the
furniture, the clothing of the rich, in a little time, become useful to the
inferior and middling ranks of people. They are able to purchase them when
their superiors grow weary of them, and the general accommodation of the
whole people is thus gradually improved, when this mode of expense becomes
universal among men of fortune. In countries which have long been rich, you
will frequently find the inferior ranks of people in possession both of houses
and furniture perfectly good and entire, but of which neither the one could
have been built, nor the other have been made for their use. What was formerly
a seat of the family of Seymour is now an inn upon the Bath road. The marriage-bed
of James the First of Great Britain, which his queen brought with her from
Denmark as a present fit for a sovereign to make to a sovereign, was, a few
years ago, the ornament of an alehouse at Dunfermline. In some ancient cities,
which either have been long stationary, or have gone somewhat to decay, you
will sometimes scarce find a single house which could have been built for
its present inhabitants. If you go into those houses too, you will frequently
find many excellent, though antiquated pieces of furniture, which are still
very fit for use, and which could as little have been made for them. Noble
palaces, magnificent villas, great collections of books, statues, pictures
and other curiosities, are frequently both an ornament and an honour, not
only to the neighbourhood, but to the whole country to which they belong.
Versailles is an ornament and an honour to France, Stowe and Wilton to England.
Italy still continues to command some sort of veneration by the number of
monuments of this kind which it possesses, though the wealth which produced
them has decayed, and though the genius which planned them seems to be extinguished,
perhaps from not having the same employment.
The expense too, which is laid out in durable commodities, is favourable,
not only to accumulation, but to frugality. If a person should at any time
exceed in it, he can easily reform without exposing himself to the censure
of the public. To reduce very much the number of his servants, to reform
his table from great profusion to great frugality, to lay down his equipage
after he has once set it up, are changes which cannot escape the observation
of his neighbours, and which are supposed to imply some acknowledgment of
preceding bad conduct. Few, therefore, of those who have once been so unfortunate
as to launch out too far into this sort of expense, have afterwards the courage
to reform, till ruin and bankruptcy oblige them. But if a person has, at
any time, been at too great an expense in building, in furniture, in books
or pictures, no imprudence can be inferred from his changing his conduct.
These are things in which further expense is frequently rendered unnecessary
by former expense; and when a person stops short, he appears to do so, not
because he has exceeded his fortune, but because he has satisfied his fancy.
The expense, besides, that is laid out in durable commodities gives maintenance,
commonly, to a greater number of people than that which is employed in the
most profuse hospitality. Of two or three hundredweight of provisions, which
may sometimes be served up at a great festival, one half, perhaps, is thrown
to the dunghill, and there is always a great deal wasted and abused. But
if the expense of this entertainment had been employed in setting to work
masons, carpenters, upholsterers, mechanics, etc., a quantity of provisions,
of equal value, would have been distributed among a still greater number
of people who would have bought them in pennyworths and pound weights, and
not have lost or thrown away a single ounce of them. In the one way, besides,
this expense maintains productive, in the other unproductive hands. In the
one way, therefore, it increases, in the other, it does not increase, the
exchangeable value of the annual produce of the land and labour of the country.