Book
Five:
OF
THE REVENUE OF THE SOVEREIGN OR COMMONWEALTH.
CHAPTER
II
Of the Sources
of the General or Public Revenue of the Society
The revenue which must defray, not only the expense of defending
the society and of supporting the dignity of the chief magistrate,
but all the other necessary expenses of government for which
the constitution of the state has not provided any particular
revenue, may be drawn either, first, from some fund which peculiarly
belongs to the sovereign or commonwealth, and which is independent
of the revenue of the people; or, secondly, from the revenue
of the
people.
Part
1: Of the Funds or Sources of Revenue which may peculiarly
belong to the Sovereign or Commonwealth
The
funds or sources of revenue which may peculiarly belong to
the sovereign or commonwealth must consist either in stock
or in land.
The sovereign, like any other owner of stock, may derive a
revenue from it, either by employing it himself, or by lending
it. His revenue is in the one case profit, in the other interest.
The revenue of a Tartar or Arabian chief consists in profit.
It arises principally from the milk and increase of his own
herds and flocks, of which he himself superintends the management,
and is the principal shepherd or herdsman of his own horde
or tribe. It is, however, in this earliest and rudest state
of civil government only that profit has ever made the principal
part of the public revenue of a monarchial state.
Small republics have sometimes derived a considerable revenue
from the profit of mercantile projects. The republic of Hamburg
is said to do so from the profits of a public wine cellar and
apothecary's shop. The state cannot be very great of which
the sovereign has leisure to carry on the trade of a wine merchant
or apothecary. The profit of a public bank has been a source
of revenue to more considerable states. It has been so not
only to Hamburg, but to Venice and Amsterdam. A revenue of
this kind has even by some people been thought not below the
attention of so great an empire as that of Great Britain. Reckoning
the ordinary dividend of the Bank of England at five and a
half per cent and its capital at ten millions seven hundred
and eighty thousand pounds, the net annual profit, after paying
the expense of management, must amount, it is said, to five
hundred and ninety-two thousand nine hundred pounds. Government,
it is pretended, could borrow this capital at three per cent
interest, and by taking the management of the bank into its
own hands, might make a clear profit of two hundred and sixty-nine
thousand five hundred pounds a year. The orderly, vigilant,
and parsimonious administration of such aristocracies as those
of Venice and Amsterdam is extremely proper, it appears from
experience, for the management of a mercantile project of this
kind. But whether such a government as that of England- which,
whatever may be its virtues, has never been famous for good
economy; which, in time of peace, has generally conducted itself
with the slothful and negligent profusion that is perhaps natural
to monarchies; and in time of war has constantly acted with
all the thoughtless extravagance that democracies are apt to
fall into- could be safely trusted with the management of such
a project, must at least be good deal more doubtful.
The post office is properly a mercantile project. The government
advances the expense of establishing the different offices,
and of buying or hiring the necessary horses or carriages,
and is repaid with a large profit by the duties upon what is
carried. It is perhaps the only mercantile project which has
been successfully managed by, I believe, every sort of government.
The capital to be advanced is not very considerable. There
is no mystery in the business. The returns are not only certain,
but immediate.
Princes, however, have frequently engaged in many other mercantile
projects, and have been willing, like private persons, to mend
their fortunes by becoming adventurers in the common branches
of trade. They have scarce ever succeeded. The profusion with
which the affairs of princes are always managed renders it
almost impossible that they should. The agents of a prince
regard the wealth of their master as inexhaustible; are careless
at what price they buy; are careless at what price they sell;
are careless at what expense they transport his goods from
one place to another. Those agents frequently live with the
profusion of princes, and sometimes too, in spite of that profusion,
and by a proper method of making up their accounts, acquire
the fortunes of princes. It was thus, as we are told by Machiavel,
that the agents of Lorenzo of Medicis, not a prince of mean
abilities, carried on his trade. The republic of Florence was
several times obliged to pay the debt into which their extravagance
had involved him. He found it convenient, accordingly, to give
up the business of merchant, the business to which his family
had originally owed their fortune, and in the latter part of
his life to employ both what remained of that fortune, and
the revenue of the state of which he had the disposal, in projects
and expenses more suitable to his station.
No two characters seem more inconsistent than those of trader
and sovereign. If the trading spirit of the English East India
Company renders them very bad sovereigns, the spirit of sovereignty
seems to have rendered them equally bad traders. While they
were traders only they managed their trade successfully, and
were able to pay from their profits a moderate dividend to
the proprietors of their stock. Since they became sovereigns,
with a revenue which, it is said, was originally more than
three millions sterling, they have been obliged to beg extraordinary
assistance of government in order to avoid immediate bankruptcy.
In their former situation, their servants in India considered
themselves as the clerks of merchants: in their present situation,
those servants consider themselves as the ministers of sovereigns.
A state may sometimes derive some part of its public revenue
from the interest of money, as well as from the profits of
stock. If it has amassed a treasure, it may lend a part of
that treasure either to foreign states, or to its own subjects.
The canton of Berne derives a considerable revenue by lending
a part of its treasure to foreign states; that is, by placing
it in the public funds of the different indebted nations of
Europe, chiefly in those of France and England. The security
of this revenue must depend, first, upon the security of the
funds in which it is placed, or upon the good faith of the
government which has the management of them; and, secondly,
upon the certainty or probability of the continuance of peace
with the debtor nation. In the case of a war, the very first
act of hostility, on the part of the debtor nation, might be
the forfeiture of the funds of its creditor. This policy of
lending money to foreign states is, so far as I know, peculiar
to the canton of Berne.
The city of Hamburg has established a sort of public pawnshop,
which lends money to the subjects of the state upon pledges
at six per cent interest. This pawnshop or Lombard, as it is
called, affords a revenue, it is pretended, to the state of
a hundred and fifty thousand crowns, which, at four and sixpence
the crown, amounts to L33,750 sterling.
The government of Pennsylvania, without amassing any treasure,
invented a method of lending, not money indeed, but what is
equivalent to money, to its subjects. By advancing to private
people at interest, and upon land security to double the value,
paper bills of credit to be redeemed fifteen years after their
date, and in the meantime made transferable from hand to hand
like bank notes, and declared by act of assembly to be a legal
tender in all payments from one inhabitant of the province
to another, it raised a moderate revenue, which went a considerable
way towards defraying an annual expense of about L4500, the
whole ordinary expense of that frugal and orderly government.
The success of an expedient of this kind must have depended
upon three different circumstances; first, upon the demand
for some other instrument of commerce besides gold and silver
money; or upon the demand for such a quantity of consumable
stock as could not be had without sending abroad the greater
part of their gold and silver money in order to purchase it;
secondly, upon the good credit of the government which made
use of this expedient; and, thirdly, upon the moderation with
which it was used, the whole value of the paper bills of credit
never exceeding that of the gold and silver money which would
have been necessary for carrying on their circulation had there
been no paper bills of credit. The same expedient was upon
different occasions adopted by several other American colonies:
but, from want of this moderation, it produced, in the greater
part of them, much more disorder than conveniency.
The unstable and perishable nature of stock and credit, however,
render them unfit to be trusted to as the principal funds of
that sure, steady, and permanent revenue which can alone give
security and dignity to government. The government of no great
nation that was advanced beyond the shepherd state seems ever
to have derived the greater part of its public revenue from
such sources.
Land is a fund of a more stable and permanent nature; and
the rent of public lands, accordingly, has been the principal
source of the public revenue of many a great nation that was
much advanced beyond the shepherd state. From the produce or
rent of the public lands, the ancient republics of Greece and
Italy derived, for a long time, the greater part of that revenue
which defrayed the necessary expenses of the commonwealth.
The rent of the crown lands constituted for a long time the
greater part of the revenue of the ancient sovereigns of Europe.
War and the preparation for war are the two circumstances
which in modern times occasion the greater part of the necessary
expense of all great states. But in the ancient republics of
Greece and Italy every citizen was a soldier, who both served
and prepared himself for service at his own expense. Neither
of those two circumstances, therefore, could occasion any very
considerable expense to the state. The rent of a very moderate
landed estate might be fully sufficient for defraying all the
other necessary expenses of government.
In the ancient monarchies of Europe, the manners and customs
of the times sufficiently Prepared the great body of the people
for war; and when they took the field, they were, by the condition
of their feudal tenures, to be maintained either at their own
expense, or at that of their immediate lords, without bringing
any new charge upon the sovereign. The other expenses of government
were, the greater part of them, very moderate. The administration
of justice, it has been shown, instead of being a cause of
expense, was a source of revenue. The labour of the country
people, for three days before and for three days after harvest,
was thought a fund sufficient for making and maintaining all
the bridges, highways, and other public works which the commerce
of the country was supposed to require. In those days the principal
expense of the sovereign seems to have consisted in the maintenance
of his own family and household. The officers of his household,
accordingly, were then the great officers of state. The lord
treasurer received his rents. The lord steward and lord chamberlain
looked after the expense of his family. The care of his stables
was committed to the lord constable and the lord marshal. His
houses were all built in the form of castles, and seem to have
been the principal fortresses which he possessed. The keepers
of those houses or castles might be considered as a sort of
military governors. They seem to have been the only military
officers whom it was necessary to maintain in time of peace.
In these circumstances the rent of a great landed estate might,
upon ordinary occasions, very well defray all the necessary
expenses of government.
In the present state of the greater part of the civilised
monarchies of Europe, the rent of all the lands in the country,
managed as they probably would be if they all belonged to one
proprietor, would scarce perhaps amount to the ordinary revenue
which they levy upon the people even in peaceable times. The
ordinary revenue of Great Britain, for example, including not
only what is necessary for defraying the current expense of
the year, but for paying the interest of the public debts,
and for sinking a part of the capital of those debts, amounts
to upwards of ten millions a year. But the land-tax, at four
shillings in the pound, falls short of two millions a year.
This land-tax, as it is called, however, is supposed to be
one-fifth, not only of the rent of all the land, but of that
of all the houses, and of the interest of all the capital stock
of Great Britain, that part of it only excepted which is either
let to the public, or employed as farming stock in the cultivation
of land. A very considerable part of the produce of this tax
arises from the rent of houses, and the interest of capital
stock. The land-tax of the city of London, for example, at
four shillings in the pound, amounts to L123,399 6s. 7d. That
of the city of Westminster, to L63,092 1s. 5d. That of the
palaces of Whitehall and St. James's, to L30,754 6s. 3d. A
certain proportion of the land-tax is in the same manner assessed
upon all the other cities and towns corporate in the kingdom,
and arises almost altogether, either from the rent of houses,
or from what is supposed to be the interest of trading and
capital stock. According to the estimation, therefore, by which
Great Britain is rated to the land-tax, the whole mass of revenue
arising from the rent of all the lands, from that of all the
houses, and from the interest of all the capital stock, that
part of it only excepted which is either lent to the public,
or employed in the cultivation of land, does not exceed ten
millions sterling a year, the ordinary revenue which government
levies upon the people even in peaceable times. The estimation
by which Great Britain is rated to the land-tax is, no doubt,
taking the whole kingdom at an average, very much below the
real value; though in several particular counties and districts
it is said to be nearly equal to that value. The rent of the
lands alone, exclusively of that of houses, and of the interest
of stock, has by many people been estimated at twenty millions,
an estimation made in a great measure at random, and which,
I apprehend, is as likely to be above as below the truth. But
if the lands of Great Britain, in the present state of their
cultivation, do not afford a rent of more than twenty millions
a year, they could not well afford the half, most probably
not the fourth part of that rent, if they all belonged to a
single proprietor, and were put under the negligent, expensive,
and oppressive management of his factors and agents. The crown
lands of Great Britain do not at present afford the fourth
part of the rent which could probably be drawn from them if
they were the property of private persons. If the crown lands
were more extensive, it is probable they would be still worse
managed.
The revenue which the great body of the people derives from
land is in proportion, not to the rent, but to the produce
of the land. The whole annual produce of the land of every
country, if we except what is reserved for seed, is either
annually consumed by the great body of the people, or exchanged
for something else that is consumed by them. Whatever keeps
down the produce of the land below what it would otherwise
rise to keeps down the revenue of the great body of the people
still more than it does that of the proprietors of land. The
rent of land, that portion of the produce which belongs to
the proprietors, is scarce anywhere in Great Britain supposed
to be more than a third part of the whole produce. If the land
which in one state of cultivation affords a rent of ten millions
sterling a year would in another afford a rent of twenty millions,
the rent being, in both cases, supposed a third part of the
produce, the revenue of the proprietors would be less than
it otherwise might be by ten millions a year only; but the
revenue of the great body of the people would be less than
it otherwise might be by thirty millions a year, deducting
only what would be necessary for seed. The population of the
country would be less by the number of people which thirty
millions a year, deducting always the seed, could maintain
according to the particular mode of living and expense which
might take place in the different ranks of men among whom the
remainder was distributed.
Though there is not at present, in Europe, any civilised state
of any kind which derives the greater part of its public revenue
from the rent of lands which are the property of the state,
yet in all the great monarchies of Europe there are still many
large tracts of land which belong to the crown. They are generally
forest; and sometimes forest where, after travelling several
miles, you will scarce find a single tree; a mere waste and
loss of country in respect both of produce and population.
In every great monarchy of Europe the sale of the crown lands
would produce a very large sum of money, which, if applied
to the payment of the public debts, would deliver from mortgage
a much greater revenue than any which those lands have ever
afforded to the crown. In countries where lands, improved and
cultivated very highly, and yielding at the time of sale as
great a rent as can easily be got from them, commonly sell
at thirty years' purchase, the unimproved, uncultivated, and
low-rented crown lands might well be expected to sell at forty,
fifty, or sixty years' purchase. The crown might immediately
enjoy the revenue which this great price would redeem from
mortgage. In the course of a few years it would probably enjoy
another revenue. When the crown lands had become private property,
they would, in the course of a few years, become well improved
and well cultivated. The increase of their produce would increase
the population of the country by augmenting the revenue and
consumption of the people. But the revenue which the crown
derives from the duties of customs and excise would necessarily
increase with the revenue and consumption of the people.
The revenue which, in any civilised monarchy, the crown derives
from the crown lands, though it appears to cost nothing to
individuals, in reality costs more to the society than perhaps
any other equal revenue which the crown enjoys. It would, in
all cases, be for the interest of the society to replace this
revenue to the crown by some other equal revenue, and to divide
the lands among the people, which could not well be done better,
perhaps, than by exposing them to public sale.
Lands for the purposes of pleasure and magnificence- parks,
gardens, public walks, etc., possessions which are everywhere
considered as causes of expense, not as sources of revenue-
seem to be the only lands which, in a great and civilised monarchy,
ought to belong to the crown.
Public stock and public lands, therefore, the two sources
of revenue which may peculiarly belong to the sovereign or
commonwealth, being both improper and insufficient funds for
defraying the necessary expense of any great and civilised
state, it remains that this expense must, the greater part
of it, be defrayed by taxes of one kind or another; the people
contributing a part of their own private revenue in order to
make up a public revenue to the sovereign or commonwealth.
Part 2: Of Taxes
The private revenue of individuals, it has been shown in the
first book of this Inquiry, arises ultimately from three different
sources: Rent, Profit, and Wages. Every tax must finally be paid
from some one or other of those three different sorts of revenue,
or from all of them indifferently. I shall endeavour to give
the best account I can, first, of those taxes which, it is intended,
should fall upon rent; secondly, of those which, it is intended,
should fall upon profit; thirdly, of those which, it is intended,
should fall upon wages; and, fourthly, of those which, it is
intended, should fall indifferently upon all those three different
sources of private revenue. The particular consideration of each
of these four different sorts of taxes will divide the second
part of the present chapter into four articles, three of which
will require several other subdivisions. Many of those taxes,
it will appear from the following review, are not finally paid
from the fund, or source of revenue, upon which it was intended
they should fall.
Before I enter upon the examination of particular taxes, it
is necessary to premise the four following maxims with regard
to taxes in general.
I. The subjects of every state ought to contribute
towards the support of the government, as nearly as possible,
in proportion to their respective abilities; that is, in proportion
to the revenue which they respectively enjoy under the protection
of the state. The expense of government to the individuals
of a great nation is like the expense of management to the
joint tenants of a great estate, who are all obliged to contribute
in proportion to their respective interests in the estate.
In the observation or neglect of this maxim consists what is
called the equality or inequality of taxation. Every tax, it
must be observed once for all, which falls finally upon one
only of the three sorts of revenue above mentioned, is necessarily
unequal in so far as it does not affect the other two. In the
following examination of different taxes I shall seldom take
much further notice of this sort of inequality, but shall,
in most cases, confine my observations to that inequality which
is occasioned by a particular tax falling unequally even upon
that particular sort of private revenue which is affected by
it.
II. The tax which each individual is bound
to pay ought to be certain, and not arbitrary. The time of
payment, the manner of payment, the quantity to be paid, ought
all to be clear and plain to the contributor, and to every
other person. Where it is otherwise, every person subject to
the tax is put more or less in the power of the tax-gathered,
who can either aggravate the tax upon any obnoxious contributor,
or extort, by the terror of such aggravation, some present
or perquisite to himself. The uncertainty of taxation encourages
the insolence and favours the corruption of an order of men
who are naturally unpopular, even where they are neither insolent
nor corrupt. The certainty of what each individual ought to
pay is, in taxation, a matter of so great importance that a
very considerable degree of inequality, it appears, I believe,
from the experience of all nations, is not near so great an
evil as a very small degree of uncertainty.
III. Every tax ought to be levied at the
time, or in the manner, in which it is most likely to be convenient
for the contributor to pay it. A tax upon the rent of land
or of houses, payable at the same term at which such rents
are usually paid, is levied at the time when it is most likely
to be convenient for the contributor to pay; or, when he is
most likely to have wherewithal to pay. Taxes upon such consumable
goods as are articles of luxury are all finally paid by the
consumer, and generally in a manner that is very convenient
for him. He pays them by little and little, as he has occasion
to buy the goods. As he is at liberty, too, either to buy,
or not to buy, as he pleases, it must be his own fault if he
ever suffers any considerable inconveniency from such taxes.
IV. Every tax ought to be so contrived as
both to take out and to keep out of the pockets of the people
as little as possible over and above what it brings into the
public treasury of the state. A tax may either take out or
keep out of the pockets of the people a great deal more than
it brings into the public treasury, in the four following ways.
First, the levying of it may require a great number of officers,
whose salaries may eat up the greater part of the produce of
the tax, and whose perquisites may impose another additional
tax upon the people. Secondly, it may obstruct the industry
the people, and discourage them from applying to certain branches
of business which might give maintenance and unemployment to
great multitudes. While it obliges the people to pay, it may
thus diminish, or perhaps destroy, some of the funds which
might enable them more easily to do so. Thirdly, by the forfeitures
and other penalties which those unfortunate individuals incur
who attempt unsuccessfully to evade the tax, it may frequently
ruin them, and thereby put an end to the benefit which the
community might have received from the employment of their
capitals. An injudicious tax offers a great temptation to smuggling.
But the penalties of smuggling must rise in proportion to the
temptation. The law, contrary to all the ordinary principles
of justice, first creates the temptation, and then punishes
those who yield to it; and it commonly enhances the punishment,
too, in proportion to the very circumstance which ought certainly
to alleviate it, the temptation to commit the crime. Fourthly,
by subjecting the people to the frequent visits and the odious
examination of the tax-gatherers, it may expose them to much
unnecessary trouble, vexation, and oppression; and though vexation
is not, strictly speaking, expense, it is certainly equivalent
to the expense at which every man would be willing to redeem
himself from it. It is in some one or other of these four different
ways that taxes are frequently so much more burdensome to the
people than they are beneficial to the sovereign.
The evident justice and utility of the foregoing maxims have
recommended them more or less to the attention of all nations.
All nations have endeavoured, to the best of their judgment,
to render their taxes as equal as they could contrive; as certain,
as convenient to the contributor, both in the time and in the
mode of payment, and, in proportion to the revenue which they
brought to the prince, as little burdensome to the people.
The following short review of some of the principal taxes which
have taken place in different ages and countries will show
that the endeavours of all nations have not in this respect
been equally successful.
Article I: Taxes upon Rent. Taxes upon the Rent of Land
A tax upon the rent of land may either every district being valued
at a certain rent, be imposed according to a certain canon, which
valuation is not afterwards to be altered, or it may be imposed
in such a manner as to vary with every variation in the real
rent of the land, and to rise or fall with the improvement or
declension of its cultivation.
A land-tax which, like that of Great Britain, is assessed
upon each district according to a certain invariable canon,
though it should be equal at the time of its first establishment,
necessarily becomes unequal in process of time, according to
the unequal degrees of improvement or neglect in the cultivation
of the different parts of the country. In England, the valuation
according to which the different countries and parishes were
assessed to the land-tax by the 4th of William and Mary was
very unequal even at its first establishment. This tax, therefore,
so far offends against the first of the four maxims above mentioned.
It is perfectly agreeable to the other three. It is perfectly
certain. The time of payment for the tax, being the same as
that for the rent, is as convenient as it can be to the contributor
though the landlord is in all cases the real contributor, the
tax is commonly advanced by the tenant, to whom the landlord
is obliged to allow it in the payment of the rent. This tax
is levied by a much smaller number of officers than any other
which affords nearly the same revenue. As the tax upon each
district does not rise with the rise of the rent, the sovereign
does not share in the profits of the landlord's improvements.
Those improvements sometimes contribute, indeed, to the discharge
of the other landlords of the district. But the aggravation
of the tax which may sometimes occasion upon a particular estate
is always so very small that it never can discourage those
improvements, nor keep down the produce of the land below what
it would otherwise rise to. As it has no tendency to diminish
the quantity, it can have none to raise the price of that produce.
It does not obstruct the industry of the people. It subjects
the landlord to no other inconveniency besides the unavoidable
one of paying the tax.
The advantage, however, which the landlord has derived from
the invariable constancy of the valuation by which all the
lands of Great Britain are rated to the land-tax, has been
principally owing to some circumstances altogether extraneous
to the nature of the tax.
It has been owing in part to the great prosperity of almost
every part of the country, the rents of almost all the estates
of Great Britain having, since the time when this valuation
was first established, been continually rising, and scarce
any of them having fallen. The landlords, therefore, have almost
all gained the difference between the tax which they would
have paid according to the present rent of their estates, and
that which they actually pay according to the ancient valuation.
Had the state of the country been different, had rents been
gradually falling in consequence of the declension of cultivation,
the landlords would almost all have lost this difference. In
the state of things which has happened to take place since
the revolution, the constancy of the valuation has been advantageous
to the landlord and hurtful to the sovereign. In a different
state of things it might have been advantageous to the sovereign
and hurtful to the landlord.
As the tax is made payable in money, so the valuation of the
land is expressed in money. Since the establishment of this
valuation the value of silver has been pretty uniform, and
there has been no alteration in the standard of the coin either
as to weight or fineness. Had silver risen considerably in
its value, as it seems to have done in the course of the two
centuries which preceded the discovery of the mines of America,
the constancy of the valuation might have proved very oppressive
to the landlord. Had silver fallen considerably in its value,
as it certainly did for about a century at least after the
discovery of those mines, the same constancy of valuation would
have reduced very much this branch of the revenue of the sovereign.
Had any considerable alteration been made in the standard of
the money, either by sinking the same quantity of silver to
a lower denomination, or by raising it to a higher; had an
ounce of silver, for example, instead of being coined into
five shillings and twopence, been coined either into pieces
which bore so low a denomination as two shillings and sevenpence,
or into pieces which bore so high a one as ten shillings and
fourpence, it would in the one case have hurt the revenue of
the proprietor, in the other that of the sovereign.
In circumstances, therefore, somewhat different from those
which have actually taken place, this constancy of valuation
might have been a very great inconveniency, either to the contributors,
or to the commonwealth. In the course of ages such circumstances,
however, must, at some time or other, happen. But though empires,
like all the other works of men, have all hitherto proved mortal,
yet every empire aims at immortality. Every constitution, therefore,
which it is meant should be as permanent as the empire itself,
ought to be convenient, not in certain circumstances only,
but in all circumstances; or ought to be suited, not to those
circumstances which are transitory, occasional, or accidental,
but to those which are necessary and therefore always the same.
A tax upon the rent of land which varies with every variation
of the rent, or which rises and falls according to the improvement
or neglect of cultivation, is recommended by that sect of men
of letters in France who call themselves The Economists as
the most equitable of all taxes. All taxes, they pretend, fall
ultimately upon the rent of land, and ought therefore to be
imposed equally upon the fund which must finally pay them.
That all taxes ought to fall as equally as possible upon the
fund which must finally pay them is certainly true. But without
entering into the disagreeable discussion of the metaphysical
arguments by which they support their very ingenious theory,
it will sufficiently appear, from the following review, what
are the taxes which fall finally upon the rent of the land,
and what are those which fall finally upon some other fund.
In the Venetian territory all the arable lands which are given
in lease to farmers are taxed at a tenth of the rent. The leases
are recorded in a public register which is kept by the officers
of revenue in each province or district. When the proprietor
cultivates his own lands, they are valued according to an equitable
estimation, and he is allowed a deduction of one-fifth of the
tax, so that for such lands he pays only eight instead of ten
per cent of the supposed rent.
A land-tax of this kind is certainly more equal than the land-tax
of England. It might not, perhaps, be altogether so certain,
and the assessment of the tax might frequently occasion a good
deal more trouble to the landlord. It might, too, be a good
deal more expensive in the levying.
Such a system of administration, however, might perhaps be
contrived as would, in a great measure, both prevent this uncertainty
and moderate this expense.
The landlord and tenant, for example, might jointly be obliged
to record their lease in a public register. Proper penalties
might be enacted against concealing or misrepresenting any
of the conditions; and if part of those penalties were to be
paid to either of the two parties who informed against and
convicted the other of such concealment or misrepresentation,
it would effectually deter them from combining together in
order to defraud the public revenue. All the conditions of
the lease might be sufficiently known from such a record.
Some landlords, instead of raising the rent, take a fine for
the renewal of the lease. This practice is in most cases the
expedient of a spendthrift, who for a sum of ready money sells
a future revenue of much greater value. It is in most cases,
therefore, hurtful to the landlords. It is frequently hurtful
to the tenant, and it is always hurtful to the community. It
frequently takes from the tenant so great a part of his capital,
and thereby diminishes so much his ability to cultivate the
land, that he finds it more difficult to pay a small rent than
it would otherwise have been to pay a great one. Whatever diminishes
his ability to cultivate, necessarily keeps down, below what
it would otherwise have been, the most important part of the
revenue of the community. By rendering the tax upon such fines
a good deal heavier than upon the ordinary rent, this hurtful
practice might be discouraged, to the no small advantage of
all the different parties concerned, of the landlord, of the
tenant, of the sovereign, and of the whole community.
Some leases prescribe to the tenant a certain mode of cultivation
and a certain succession of crops during the whole continuance
of the lease. This condition, which is generally the effect
of the landlord's conceit of his own superior knowledge (a
conceit in most cases very ill founded), ought always to be
considered as an additional rent; as a rent in service instead
of a rent in money. In order to discourage the practice, which
is generally a foolish one, this species of rent might be valued
rather high, and consequently taxed somewhat higher than common
money rents.
Some landlords, instead of a rent in money, require a rent
in kind, in corn, cattle, poultry, wine, oil, etc.; others,
again, require a rent in service. Such rents are always more
hurtful to the tenant than beneficial to the landlord. They
either take more or keep more out of the pocket of the former
than they put into that of the latter. In every country where
they take place the tenants are poor and beggarly, pretty much
according to the degree in which they take place. By valuing,
in the same manner, such rents rather high, and consequently
taxing them somewhat higher than common money rents, a practice
which is hurtful to the whole community might perhaps be sufficiently
discouraged.
When the landlord chose to occupy himself a part of his own
lands, the rent might be valued according to an equitable arbitration
of the farmers and landlords in the neighbourhood, and a moderate
abatement of the tax might be granted to him, in the same manner
as in the Venetian territory, provided the rent of the lands
which he occupied did not exceed a certain sum. It is of importance
that the landlord should be encouraged to cultivate a part
of his own land. His capital is generally greater than that
of the tenant, and with less skill he can frequently raise
a greater produce. The landlord can afford to try experiments,
and is generally disposed to do so. His unsuccessful experiments
occasion only a moderate loss to himself. His successful ones
contribute to the improvement and better cultivation of the
whole country. It might be of importance, however, that the
abatement of the tax should encourage him to cultivate to a
certain extent only. If the landlords should, the greater part
of them, be tempted to farm the whole of their own lands, the
country (instead of sober and industrious tenants, who are
bound by their own interest to cultivate as well as their capital
and skill will allow them) would be filled with idle and profligate
bailiffs, whose abusive management would soon degrade the cultivation
and reduce the annual produce of the land, to the diminution,
not only of the revenue of their masters, but of the most important
part of that of the whole society.
Such a system of administration might, perhaps, free a tax
of this kind from any degree of uncertainty which could occasion
either oppression or inconveniency of the contributor; and
might at the same time serve to introduce into the common management
of land such a plan or policy as might contribute a good deal
to the general improvement and good cultivation of the country.
The expense of levying a land-tax which varied with every
variation of the rent would no doubt be somewhat greater than
that of levying one which was already rated according to a
fixed valuation. Some additional expense would necessarily
be incurred both by the different register offices which it
would be proper to establish in the different districts of
the country, and by the different valuations which might occasionally
be made of the lands which the proprietor chose to occupy himself.
The expense of all this, however, might be very moderate, and
much below what is incurred in the levying of many other taxes
which afford a very inconsiderable revenue in comparison of
what might easily be drawn from a tax of this kind.
The discouragement which a variable land-tax of this kind
might give to the improvement of land seems to be the most
important objection which can be made to it. The landlord would
certainly be less disposed to improve when the sovereign, who
contributed nothing to the expense, was to share in the profit
of the improvement. Even this objection might perhaps be obviated
by allowing the landlord, before he began his improvement,
to ascertain, in conjunction with the officers of revenue,
the actual value of his lands according to the equitable arbitration
of a certain number of landlords and farmers in the neighborhood,
equally chosen by both parties, and by rating him according
to this valuation for such a number of years as might be fully
sufficient for his complete indemnification. To draw the attention
of the sovereign towards the improvement of the land, from
a regard to the increase of his own revenue, is one of the
principal advantages proposed by this species of land-tax.
The term, therefore, allowed for the indemnification of the
landlord ought not to be a great deal longer than what was
necessary for that purpose, lest the remoteness of the interest
should discourage too much this attention. It had better, however,
be somewhat too long than in any respect too short. No incitement
to the attention of the sovereign can ever counterbalance the
smallest discouragement to that of the landlord. The attention
of the sovereign can be at best but a very general and vague
consideration of what is likely to contribute to the better
cultivation of the greater part of his dominions. The attention
of the landlord is a particular and minute consideration of
what is likely to be the most advantageous application of every
inch of ground upon his estate. The principal attention of
the sovereign ought to be to encourage, by every means in his
power, the attention both of the landlord and of the farmer,
by allowing both to pursue their own interest in their own
way and according to their own judgment; by giving to both
the most perfect security that they shall enjoy the full recompense
of their own industry; and by procuring to both the most extensive
market for every part of their produce, in consequence of establishing
the easiest and safest communications both by land and by water
through every part of his own dominions as well as the most
unbounded freedom of exportation to the dominions of all other
princes.
If by such a system of administration a tax of this kind could
be so managed as to give, not only no discouragement, but,
on the contrary, some encouragement to the improvement of land,
it does not appear likely to occasion any other inconveniency
to the landlord, except always the unavoidable one of being
obliged to pay the tax.
In all the variations of the state of the society, in the
improvement and in the declension of agriculture; in all the
variations in the value of silver, and in all those in the
standard of the coin, a tax of this kind would, of its own
accord and without any attention of government, readily suit
itself to the actual situation of things, and would be equally
just and equitable in all those different changes. It would,
therefore, be much more proper to be established as a perpetual
and unalterable regulation, or as what is called a fundamental
law of the commonwealth, than any tax which was always to be
levied according to a certain valuation.
Some states, instead of the simple and obvious expedient of
a register of leases, have had recourse to the laborious and
expensive one of an actual survey and valuation of all the
lands in the country. They have suspected, probably, that the
lessor and lessee, in order to defraud the public revenue,
might combine to conceal the real terms of the lease. Domesday-Book
seems to have been the result of a very accurate survey of
this kind.
In the ancient dominions of the King of Prussia, the land-tax
is assessed according to an actual survey and valuation, which
is reviewed and altered from time to time. According to that
valuation, the lay proprietors pay from twenty to twenty-five
per cent of their revenue. Ecclesiastics from forty to forty-five
per cent. The survey and valuation of Silesia was made by order
of the present king; it is said with great accuracy. According
to that valuation, the lands belonging to the Bishop of Breslaw
are taxed at twenty-five per cent of their rent. The other
revenues of the ecclesiastics of both religions, at fifty per
cent. The commanderies of the Teutonic order, and of that of
Malta, at forty per cent. Lands held by a noble tenure, at
thirty-eight and one-third per cent. Lands held by a base tenure,
at thirty-five and one-third per cent.
The survey and valuation of Bohemia is said to have been the
work of more than a hundred years. It was not perfected till
after the peace of 1748, by the orders of the present empress
queen. The survey of the duchy of Milan, which was begun in
the time of Charles VI, was not perfected till after 1760.
It is esteemed one of the most accurate that has ever been
made. The survey of Savoy and Piedmont was executed under the
orders of the late King of Sardinia.
In the dominions of the King of Prussia the revenue of the
church is taxed much higher than that of lay proprietors. The
revenue of the church is, the greater part of it, a burden
upon the rent of land. It seldom happens that any part of it
is applied towards the improvement of land, or is so employed
as to contribute in any respect towards increasing the revenue
of the great body of the people. His Prussian Majesty had probably,
upon that account, thought it reasonable that it should contribute
a good deal more towards relieving the exigencies of the state.
In some countries the lands of the church are exempted from
all taxes. In others they are taxed more lightly than other
lands. In the duchy of Milan, the lands which the church possessed
before 1575 are rated to the tax at a third only of their value.
In Silesia, lands held by a noble tenure are taxed three per
cent higher than those held by a base tenure. The honours and
privileges of different kinds annexed to the former, his Prussian
Majesty had probably imagined, would sufficiently compensate
to the proprietor a small aggravation of the tax; while at
the same time the humiliating inferiority of the latter would
be in some measure alleviated by being taxed somewhat more
lightly. In other countries, the system of taxation, instead
of alleviating, aggravates this inequality. In the dominions
of the King of Sardinia, and in those provinces of France which
are subject to what is called the real or predial taille, the
tax falls altogether upon the lands held by a base tenure.
Those held by a noble one are exempted.
A land-tax assessed according to a general survey and valuation,
how equal soever it may be at first, must, in the course of
a very moderate period of time, become unequal. To prevent
its becoming so would require the continual and painful attention
of government to all the variations in the state and produce
of every different farm in the country. The governments of
Prussia, of Bohemia, of Sardinia, and of the duchy of Milan
actually exert an attention of this kind; an attention so unsuitable
to the nature of government that it is not likely to be of
long continuance, and which, if it is continued, will probably
in the long-run occasion much more trouble and vexation than
it can possibly bring relief to the contributors.
In 1666, the generality of Montauban was assessed to the real
or predial taille according, it is said, to a very exact survey
and valuation. By 1727, this assessment had become altogether
unequal. In order to remedy this inconveniency, government
has found no better expedient than to impose upon the whole
generality an additional tax of a hundred and twenty thousand
livres. This additional tax is rated upon all the different
districts subject to the taille according to the old assessment.
But it is levied only upon those which in the actual state
of things are by that assessment undertaxed, and it is applied
to the relief of those which by the same assessment are overtaxed.
Two districts, for example, one of which ought in the actual
state of things to be taxed at nine hundred, the other at eleven
hundred livres, are by the old assessment both taxed at a thousand
livres. Both these districts are by the additional tax rated
at eleven hundred livres each. But this additional tax is levied
only upon the district undercharged, and it is applied altogether
to the relief of that overcharged, which consequently pays
only nine hundred livres. The government neither gains nor
loses by the additional tax, which is applied altogether to
remedy the inequalities arising from the old assessment. The
application is pretty much regulated according to the discretion
of the intendant of the generality, and must, therefore, be
in a great measure arbitrary.
Taxes
which are proportioned, not to the Rent, but to the Produce
of Land
Taxes upon the produce of land are in reality taxes upon the
rent; and though they may be originally advanced by the farmer,
are finally paid by the landlord. When a certain portion of the
produce is to be paid away for a tax, the farmer computes, as
well as he can, what the value of this portion is, one year with
another, likely to amount to, and he makes a proportionable abatement
in the rent which he agrees to pay to the landlord. There is
no farmer who does not compute beforehand what the church tithe,
which is a land-tax of this kind, is, one year with another,
likely to amount to.
The tithe, and every other land-tax of this kind, under the
appearance of perfect equality, are very unequal taxes; a certain
portion of the produce being, in different situations, equivalent
to a very different portion of the rent. In some very rich
lands the produce is so great that the one half of it is fully
sufficient to replace to the farmer his capital employed in
cultivation, together with the ordinary profits of farming
stock in the neighbourhood. The other half, or, what comes
to the same thing, the value of the other half, he could afford
to pay as rent to the landlord, if there was no tithe. But
if a tenth of the produce is taken from him in the way of tithe,
he must require an abatement of the fifth part of his rent,
otherwise he cannot get back his capital with the ordinary
profit. In this case the rent of the landlord, instead of amounting
to a half or five-tenths of the whole produce, will amount
only to four-tenths of it. In poorer lands, on the contrary,
the produce is sometimes so small, and the expense of cultivation
so great, that it requires four-fifths of the whole produce
to replace to the farmer his capital with the ordinary profit.
In this case, though there was no tithe, the rent of the landlord
could amount to no more than one-fifth or two-tenths of the
whole produce. But if the farmer pays one-tenth of the produce
in the way of tithe, he must require an equal abatement of
the rent of the landlord, which will thus be reduced to one-tenth
only of the whole produce. Upon the rent of rich lands, the
tithe may sometimes be a tax of no more than one-fifth part,
or four shillings in the pound; whereas upon that of poorer
lands, it may sometimes be a tax of one-half, or of ten shillings
in the pound.
The tithe, as it is frequently a very unequal tax upon the
rent, so it is always a great discouragement both to the improvements
of the landlord and to the cultivation of the farmer. The one
cannot venture to make the most important, which are generally
the most expensive improvements, nor the other to raise the
most valuable, which are generally too the most expensive crops,
when the church, which lays out no part of the expense, is
to share so very largely in the profit. The cultivation of
madder was for a long time confined by the tithe to the United
Provinces, which, being Presbyterian countries, and upon that
account exempted from this destructive tax, enjoyed a sort
of monopoly of that useful dyeing drug against the rest of
Europe. The late attempts to introduce the culture of this
plant into England have been made only in consequence of the
statute which enacted that five shillings an acre should be
received in lieu of all manner of tithe upon madder.
As through the greater part of Europe the church, so in many
different countries of Asia the state, is principally supported
by a land-tax, proportioned, not to the rent, but to the produce
of the land. In China, the principal revenue of the sovereign
consists in a tenth part of the produce of all lands of the
empire. This tenth part, however, is estimated so very moderately
that, in many provinces, it is said not to exceed a thirtieth
part of the ordinary produce. The land-tax or land-rent which
used to be paid to the Mahometan government of Bengal, before
that country fell into the hands of the English East India
Company, is said to have amounted to about a fifth part of
the produce. The land-tax of ancient Egypt is said likewise
to have amounted to a fifth part.
In Asia, this sort of land-tax is said to interest the sovereign
in the improvement and cultivation of land. The sovereigns
of China, those of Bengal while under the Mahometan government,
and those of ancient Egypt, are said accordingly to have been
extremely attentive to the making and maintaining of good roads
and navigable canals, in order to increase, as much as possible,
both the quantity and value of every part of the produce of
the land, by procuring to every part of it the most extensive
market which their own dominions could afford. The tithe of
the church is divided into such small portions that no one
of its proprietors can have any interest of this kind. The
parson of a parish could never find his account in making a
road or canal to a distant part of the country, in order to
extend the market for the produce of his own particular parish.
Such taxes, when destined for the maintenance of the state,
have some advantages which may serve in some measure to balance
their inconveniency. When destined for the maintenance of the
church, they are attended with nothing but inconveniency.
Taxes upon the produce of land may be levied either in kind,
or, according to a certain valuation, in money.
The parson of a parish, or a gentleman of small fortune who
lives upon his estate, may sometimes, perhaps, find some advantage
in receiving, the one his tithe, and the other his rent, in
kind. The quantity to be collected, and the district within
which it is to be collected, are so small that they both can
oversee, with their own eyes, the collection and disposal of
every part of what is due to them. A gentleman of great fortune,
who lived in the capital, would be in danger of suffering much
by the neglect, and more by the fraud of his factors and agents,
if the rents of an estate in a distant province were to be
paid to him in this manner. The loss of the sovereign from
the abuse and depredation of his tax-gatherers would necessarily
be much greater. The servants of the most careless private
person are, perhaps, more under the eye of their master than
those of the most careful prince; and a public revenue which
was paid in kind would suffer so much from the mismanagement
of the collectors that a very small part of what was levied
upon the people would ever arrive at the treasury of the prince.
Some part of the public revenue of China, however, is said
to be paid in this manner. The mandarins and other tax-gatherers
will, no doubt, find their advantage in continuing the practice
of a payment which is so much more liable to abuse than any
payment in money.
A tax upon the produce of land which is levied in money may
be levied either according to a valuation which varies with
all the variations of the market price, or according to a fixed
valuation, a bushel of wheat, for example, being always valued
at one and the same money price, whatever may be the state
of the market. The produce of a tax levied in the former way
will vary only according to the variations in the real produce
of the land, according to the improvement or neglect of cultivation.
The produce of a tax levied in the latter way will vary, not
only according to the variations in the produce of the land,
but according to both those in the value of the precious metals
and those in the quantity of those metals which is at different
times contained in coin of the same denomination. The produce
of the former will always bear the same proportion to the value
of the real produce of the land. The produce of the latter
may, at different times, bear very different proportions to
that value.
When, instead either of a certain portion of the produce of
land, or of the price of a certain portion, a certain sum of
money is to be paid in full compensation for all tax or tithe,
the tax becomes, in this case, exactly of the same nature with
the land-tax of England. It neither rises nor falls with the
rent of the land. It neither encourages nor discourages improvement.
The tithe in the greater part of those parishes which pay what
is called a Modus in lieu of all other tithe is a tax of this
kind. During the Mahometan government of Bengal, instead of
the payment in kind of a fifth part of the produce, a modus,
and, it is said, a very moderate one, was established in the
greater part of the districts or zemindaries of the country.
Some of the servants of the East India Company, under pretence
of restoring the public revenue to its proper value, have,
in some provinces, exchanged this modus for a payment in kind.
Under their management this change is likely both to discourage
cultivation, and to give new opportunities for abuse in the
collection of the public revenue which has fallen very much
below what it was said to have been when it first fell under
the management of the company. The servants of the company
may, perhaps, have profited by this change, but at the expense,
it is probable, both of their masters and of the country.
Taxes upon the Rent of House.
The rent of a house may be distinguished into two parts, of which
the one may very properly be called the Building-rent; the other
is commonly called the Ground-rent.
The building-rent is the interest or profit of the capital
expended in building the house. In order to put the trade of
a builder upon a level with other trades, it is necessary that
this rent should be sufficient, first, to pay him the same
interest which he would have got for his capital if he had
lent it upon good security; and, secondly, to keep the house
in constant repair, or, what comes to the same thing, to replace,
within a certain term of years, the capital which had been
employed in building it. The building-rent, or the ordinary
profit of building, is, therefore, everywhere regulated by
the ordinary interest of money. Where the market rate of interest
is four per cent the rent of a house which, over and above
paying the ground-rent, affords six or six and a half per cent
upon the whole expense of building, may perhaps afford a sufficient
profit to the builder. Where the market rate of interest is
five per cent, it may perhaps require seven or seven and a
half per cent. If, in proportion to the interest of money,
the trade of the builder affords at any time a much greater
profit than this, it will soon draw so much capital from other
trades as will reduce the profit to its proper level. If it
affords at any time much less than this, other trades will
soon draw so much capital from it as will again raise that
profit.
Whatever part of the whole rent of a house is over and above
what is sufficient for affording this reasonable profit naturally
goes to the ground-rent; and where the owner of the ground
and the owner of the building are two different persons, is,
in most cases, completely paid to the former. This surplus
rent is the price which the inhabitant of the house pays for
some real or supposed advantage of the situation. In country
houses at a distance from any great town, where there is plenty
of ground to choose upon, the ground-rent is scarce anything,
or no more than what the ground which the house stands upon
would pay if employed in agriculture. In country villas in
the neighborhood of some great town, it is sometimes a good
deal higher, and the peculiar conveniency or beauty of situation
is there frequently very well paid for. Ground-rents are generally
highest in the capital, and in those particular parts of it
where there happens to be the greatest demand for houses, whatever
be the reason of that demand, whether for trade and business,
for pleasure and society, or for mere vanity and fashion.
A tax upon house-rent, payable by the tenant and proportioned
to the whole rent of each house, could not, for any considerable
time at least, affect the building-rent. If the builder did
not get his reasonable profit, he would be obliged to quit
the trade; which, by raising the demand for building, would
in a short time bring back his profit to its proper level with
that of other trades. Neither would such a tax fall altogether
upon the ground-rent; but it would divide itself in such a
manner as to fall partly upon the inhabitant of the house,
and partly upon the owner of the ground.
Let us suppose, for example, that a particular person judges
that he can afford for house-rent an expense of sixty pounds
a year; and let us suppose, too, that a tax of four shillings
in the pound, or of one-fifth, payable by the inhabitant, is
laid upon house-rent. A house of sixty pounds rent will in
this case cost him seventy-two pounds a year, which is twelve
pounds more than he thinks he can afford. He will, therefore,
content himself with a worse house, or a house of fifty pounds
rent, which, with the additional ten pounds that he must pay
for the tax, will make up the sum of sixty pounds a year, the
expense which he judges he can afford; and in order to pay
the tax he will give up a part of the additional conveniency
which he might have had from a house of ten pounds a year more
rent. He will give up, I say, a part of this additional conveniency;
for he will seldom be obliged to give up the whole, but will,
in consequence of the tax, get a better house for fifty pounds
a year than he could have got if there had been no tax. For
as a tax of this kind by taking away this particular competitor,
must diminish the competition for houses of sixty pounds rent,
so it must likewise diminish it for those of fifty pounds rent,
and in the same manner for those of all other rents, except
the lowest rent, for which it would for some time increase
the competition. But the rents of every class of houses for
which the competition was diminished would necessarily be more
or less reduced. As no part of this reduction, however, could,
for any considerable time at least, affect the building-rent,
the whole of it must in the long-run necessarily fall upon
the ground-rent. The final payment of this tax, therefore,
would fall partly upon the inhabitant of the house, who, in
order to pay his share, would be obliged to give up a part
of his conveniency, and partly upon the owner of the ground,
who, in order to pay his share, would be obliged to give up
a part of his revenue. In what proportion this final payment
would be divided between them it is not perhaps very easy to
ascertain. The division would probably be very different in
different circumstances, and a tax of this kind might, according
to those different circumstances, affect very unequally both
the inhabitant of the house and the owner of the ground.
The inequality with which a tax of this kind might fall upon
the owners of different ground-rents would arise altogether
from the accidental inequality of this division. But the inequality
with which it might fall upon the inhabitants of different
houses would arise not only from this, but from another cause.
The proportion of the expense of house-rent to the whole expense
of living is different in the different degrees of fortune.
It is perhaps highest in the highest degree, and it diminishes
gradually through the inferior degrees, so as in general to
be lowest in the lowest degree. The necessaries of life occasion
the great expense of the poor. They find it difficult to get
food, and the greater part of their little revenue is spent
in getting it. The luxuries and vanities of life occasion the
principal expense of the rich, and a magnificent house embellishes
and sets off to the best advantage all the other luxuries and
vanities which they possess. A tax upon house-rents, therefore,
would in general fall heaviest upon the rich; and in this sort
of inequality there would not, perhaps, be anything very unreasonable.
It is not very unreasonable that the rich should contribute
to the public expense, not only in proportion to their revenue,
but something more than in that proportion.
The rent of houses, though it in some respects resembles the
rent of land, is in one respect essentially different from
it. The rent of land is paid for the use of a productive subject.
The land which pays it produces it. The rent of houses is paid
for the use of an unproductive subject. Neither the house nor
the ground which it stands upon produce anything. The person
who pays the rent, therefore, must draw it from some other
source of revenue distinct from the independent of this subject.
A tax upon the rent of houses, so far as it falls upon the
inhabitants, must be drawn from the same source as the rent
itself, and must be paid from their revenue, whether derived
from the wages of labour, the profits of stock, or the rent
of land. So far as it falls upon the inhabitants, it is one
of those taxes which fall, not upon one only, but indifferently
upon all the three different sources of revenue, and is in
every respect of the same nature as a tax upon any other sort
of consumable commodities. In general there is not, perhaps,
any one article of expense or consumption by which the liberality
or narrowness of a man's whole expense can be better judged
of than by his house-rent. A proportional tax upon this particular
article of expense might, perhaps, produce a more considerable
revenue than any which has hitherto been drawn from it in any
part of Europe. If the tax indeed was very high, the greater
part of people would endeavour to evade it, as much as they
could, by contenting themselves with smaller houses, and by
turning the greater part of their expense into some other channel.
The rent of houses might easily be ascertained with sufficient
accuracy by a policy of the same kind with that which would
be necessary for ascertaining the ordinary rent of land. Houses
not inhabited ought to pay no tax. A tax upon them would fall
altogether upon the proprietor, who would thus be taxed for
a subject which afforded him neither conveniency nor revenue.
Houses inhabited by the proprietor ought to be rated, not according
to the expense which they might have cost in building, but
according to the rent which an equitable arbitration might
judge them likely to bring if leased to a tenant. If rated
according to the expense which they may have cost in building,
a tax of three or four shillings in the pound, joined with
other taxes, would ruin almost all the rich and great families
of this, and, I believe, of every other civilised country.
Whoever will examine, with attention, the different town and
country houses of some of the richest and greatest families
in this country will find that, at the rate of only six and
a half or seven per cent upon the original expense of building,
their house-rent is nearly equal to the whole net rent of their
estates. It is the accumulated expense of several successive
generations, laid out upon objects of great beauty and magnificance,
indeed; but, in proportion to what they cost, of very small
exchangeable value.
Ground-rents are a still more proper subject of taxation than
the rent of houses. A tax upon ground-rents would not raise
the rents of houses. It would fall altogether upon the owner
of the ground-rent, who acts always as a monopolist, and exacts
the greatest rent which can be got for the use of his ground.
More or less can be got for it according as the competitors
happen to be richer or poorer, or can afford to gratify their
fancy for a particular spot of ground at a greater or smaller
expense. In every country the greatest number of rich competitors
is in the capital, and it is there accordingly that the highest
ground-rents are always to be found. As the wealth of those
competitors would in no respect be increased by a tax upon
ground-rents, they would not probably be disposed to pay more
for the use of the ground. Whether the tax was to be advanced
by the inhabitant, or by the owner of the ground, would be
of little importance. The more the inhabitant was obliged to
pay for the tax, the less he would incline to pay for the ground;
so that the final payment of the tax would fall altogether
upon the owner of the ground-rent. The ground-rents of uninhabited
houses ought to pay no tax.
Both ground-rents and the ordinary rent of land are a species
of revenue which the owner, in many cases, enjoys without any
care or attention of his own. Though a part of this revenue
should be taken from him in order to defray the expenses of
the state, no discouragement will thereby be given to any sort
of industry. The annual produce of the land and labour of the
society, the real wealth and revenue of the great body of the
people, might be the same after such a tax as before. Ground-rents
and the ordinary rent of land are, therefore, perhaps, the
species of revenue which can best bear to have a peculiar tax
imposed upon them.
Ground-rents seem, in this respect, a more proper subject
of peculiar taxation than even the ordinary rent of land. The
ordinary rent of land is, in many cases, owing partly at least
to the attention and good management of the landlord. A very
heavy tax might discourage too, much this attention and good
management. Ground-rents, so far as they exceed the ordinary
rent of land, are altogether owing to the good government of
the sovereign, which, by protecting the industry either of
the whole people, or of the inhabitants of some particular
place, enables them to pay so much more than its real value
for the ground which they build their houses upon; or to make
to its owner so much more than compensation for the loss which
he might sustain by this use of it. Nothing can be more reasonable
than that a fund which owes its existence to the good government
of the state should be taxed peculiarly, or should contribute
something more than the greater part of other funds, towards
the support of that government.
Though, in many different countries of Europe, taxes have
been imposed upon the rent of houses, I do not know of any
in which ground-rents have been considered as a separate subject
of taxation. The contrivers of taxes have, probably, found
some difficulty in ascertaining what part of the rent ought
to be considered as ground-rent, and what part ought to be
considered as building-rent. It should not, however, seem very
difficult to distinguish those two parts of the rent from one
another.
In Great Britain the rent of houses is supposed to be taxed
in the same proportion as the rent of land by what is called
the annual land-tax. The valuation, according to which each
different parish and district is assessed to this tax, is always
the same. It was originally extremely unequal, and it still
continues to be so. Through the greater part of the kingdom
this tax falls still more lightly upon the rent of houses than
upon that of land. In some few districts only, which were originally
rated high, and in which the rents of houses have fallen considerably,
the land-tax of three or four shillings in the pound is said
to amount to an equal proportion of the real rent of houses.
Untenanted houses, though by law subject to the tax, are, in
most districts, exempted from it by the favour of the assessors;
and this exemption sometimes occasions some little variation
in the rate of particular houses, though that of the district
is always the same. Improvements of rent, by new buildings,
repairs, etc., go to the discharge of the district, which occasions
still further variations in the rate of particular houses.
In the province of Holland every house is taxed at two and
a half per cent of its value, without any regard either to
the rent which it actually pays, or to the circumstances of
its being tenanted or untenanted. There seems to be a hardship
in obliging the proprietor to pay a tax for an untenanted house,
from which he can derive no revenue, especially so very heavy
a tax. In Holland, where the market rate of interest does not
exceed three per cent, two and a half per cent upon the whole
value of the house must, in most cases, amount to more than
a third of the building-rent, perhaps of the whole rent. The
valuation, indeed, according to which the houses are rated,
though very unequal, is said to be always below the real value.
When a house is rebuilt, improved, or enlarged, there is a
new valuation, and the tax is rated accordingly.
The contrivers of the several taxes which in England have,
at different times, been imposed upon houses, seem to have
imagined that there was some great difficulty in ascertaining,
with tolerable exactness, what was the real rent of every house.
They have regulated their taxes, therefore, according to some
more obvious circumstances, such as they had probably imagined
would, in most cases, bear some proportion to the rent.
The first tax of this kind was hearth-money, or a tax of two
shillings upon every hearth. In order to ascertain how many
hearths were in the house, it was necessary that the tax-gatherer
should enter every room in it. This odious visit rendered the
tax odious. Soon after the revolution, therefore, it was abolished
as a badge of slavery.
The next tax of this kind was a tax of two shillings upon
every dwelling-house inhabited. A house with ten windows to
pay four shillings more. A house with twenty windows and upwards
to pay eight shillings. This tax was afterwards so far altered
that houses with twenty windows, and with less than thirty,
were ordered to pay ten shillings, and those with thirty windows
and upwards to pay twenty shillings. The number of windows
can, in most cases, be counted from the outside, and, in all
cases, without entering every room in the house. The visit
of the tax-gatherer, therefore, was less offensive in this
tax than in the hearth-money.
This tax was afterwards repealed, and in the room of it was
established the window-tax, which has undergone, too, several
alterations and augmentations. The window-tax, as it stands
at present (January 1775), over and above the duty of three
shillings upon every house in England, and of one shilling
upon every house in Scotland, lays a duty upon every window,
which, in England, augments gradually from twopence, the lowest
rate, upon houses with not more than seven windows, to two
shillings, the highest rate, upon houses with twenty-five windows
and upwards.
The principal objection to all such taxes of the worst is
their inequality, an inequality of the worst kind, as they
must frequently fall much heavier upon the poor than upon the
rich. A house of ten pounds rent in a country town may sometimes
have more windows than a house of five hundred pounds rent
in London; and though the inhabitant of the former is likely
to be a much poorer man than that of the latter, yet so far
as his contribution is regulated by the window-tax, he must
contribute more to the support of the state. Such taxes are,
therefore, directly contrary to the first of the four maxims
above mentioned. They do not seem to offend much against any
of the other three.
The natural tendency of the window-tax, and of all other taxes
upon houses, is to lower rents. The more a man pays for the
tax, the less, it is evident, he can afford to pay for the
rent. Since the imposition of the window-tax, however, the
rents of houses have upon the whole risen, more or less, in
almost every town and village of Great Britain with which I
am acquainted. Such has been almost everywhere the increase
of the demand for houses, that it has raised the rents more
than the window-tax could sink them; one of the many proofs
of the great prosperity of the country, and of the increasing
revenue of its inhabitants. Had it not been for the tax, rents
would probably have risen still higher.
Article II: Taxes on Profit, or upon the Revenue arising
from Stock
The revenue or profit arising from stock naturally divides itself
into two parts; that which pays the interest, and which belongs
to the owner of the stock, and that surplus part which is over
and above what is necessary for paying the
interest.
This latter part of profit is evidently a subject not taxable
directly. It is the compensation, and in most cases it is no
more than a very moderate compensation, for the risk and trouble
of employing the stock. The employer must have this compensation,
otherwise he cannot, consistently with his own interest, continue
the employment. If he was taxed directly, therefore, in proportion
to the whole profit, he would be obliged either to raise the
rate of his profit, or to charge the tax upon the interest
of money; that is, to pay less interest. If he raised the rate
of his profit in proportion to the tax, the whole tax, though
it might be advanced by him, would be finally paid by one or
other of two different sets of people, according to the different
ways in which he might employ the stock of which he had the
management. If he employed it as a farming stock in the cultivation
of land, he could raise the rate of his profit only by retaining
a greater portion, or, what comes to the same thing, the price
of a greater portion of the produce of the land; and as this
could be done only by a reduction of rent, the final payment
of the tax would fall upon the landlord. If he employed it
as a mercantile or manufacturing stock, he could raise the
rate of his profit only by raising the price of his goods;
in which case the final payment of the tax would fall altogether
upon the consumers of those goods. If he did not raise the
rate of his profit, he would be obliged to charge the whole
tax upon that part of it which was allotted for the interest
of money. He could afford less interest for whatever stock
he borrowed, and the whole weight of the tax would in this
case fall ultimately upon the interest of money. So far as
he could not relieve himself from the tax in the one way, he
would be obliged to relieve himself in the other.
The interest of money seems at first sight a subject equally
capable of being taxed directly as the rent of land. Like the
rent of land, it is a net produce which remains after completely
compensating the whole risk and trouble of employing the stock.
As a tax upon the rent of land cannot raise rents; because
the net produce which remains after replacing the stock of
the farmer, together with his reasonable profit, cannot be
greater after the tax than before it, so, for the same reason,
a tax upon the interest of money could not raise the rate of
interest; the quantity of stock or money in the country, like
the quantity of land, being supposed to remain the same after
the tax as before it. The ordinary rate of profit, it has been
shown in the first book, is everywhere regulated by the quantity
of stock to be employed in proportion to the quantity of the
employment, or of the business which must be done by it. But
the quantity of the employment, or of the business to be done
by stock, could neither be increased nor diminished by any
tax upon the interest of money. If the quantity of the stock
to be employed, therefore, was neither increased nor diminished
by it, the ordinary rate of profit would necessarily remain
the same. But the portion of this profit necessary for compensating
the risk and trouble of the employer would likewise remain
the same, that risk and trouble being in no respect altered.
The residue, therefore, that portion which belongs to the owner
of the stock, and which pays the interest of money, would necessarily
remain the same too. At first sight, therefore, the interest
of money seems to be a subject as fit to be taxed directly
as the rent of land.
There are, however, two different circumstances which render
the interest of money a much less proper subject of direct
taxation than the rent of land.
First, the quantity and value of the land which any man possesses
can never be a secret, and can always be ascertained with great
exactness. But the whole amount of the capital stock which
he possesses is almost always a secret, and can scarce ever
be ascertained with tolerable exactness. It is liable, besides,
to almost continual variations. A year seldom passes away,
frequently not a month, sometimes scarce a single day, in which
it does not rise or fall more or less. An inquisition into
every man's private circumstances, and an inquisition which,
in order to accommodate the tax to them, watched over all the
fluctuations of his fortunes, would be a source of such continual
and endless vexation as no people could support.
Secondly, land is a subject which cannot be removed; whereas
stock easily may. The proprietor of land is necessarily a citizen
of the particular country in which his estate lies. The proprietor
of stock is properly a citizen of the world, and is not necessarily
attached to any particular country. He would be apt to abandon
the country in which he was exposed to a vexatious inquisition,
in order to be assessed to a burdensome tax, and would remove
his stock to some other country where he could either carry
on his business, or enjoy his fortune more at his ease. By
removing his stock he would put an end to all the industry
which it had maintained in the country which he left. Stock
cultivates land; stock employs labour. A tax which tended to
drive away stock from any particular country would so far tend
to dry up every source of revenue both to the sovereign and
to the society. Not only the profits of stock, but the rent
of land and the wages of labour would necessarily be more or
less diminished by its removal.
The nations, accordingly, who have attempted to tax the revenue
arising from stock, instead of any severe inquisition of this
kind, have been obliged to content themselves with some very
loose, and, therefore, more or less arbitrary, estimation.
The extreme inequality and uncertainty of a tax assessed in
this manner can be compensated only by its extreme moderation,
in consequence of which every man finds himself rated so very
much below his real revenue that he gives himself little disturbance
though his neighbour should be rated somewhat lower.
By what is called the land-tax in England, it was intended
that stock should be taxed in the same proportion as land.
When the tax upon land was at four shillings in the pound,
or at one-fifth of the supposed rent, it was intended that
stock should be taxed at one-fifth of the supposed interest.
When the present annual land-tax was first imposed, the legal
rate of interest was six per cent. Every hundred pounds stock,
accordingly, was supposed to be taxed at twenty-four shillings,
the fifth part of six pounds. Since the legal rate of interest
has been reduced to five per cent every hundred pounds stock
is supposed to be taxed at twenty shillings only. The sum to
be raised by what is called the land-tax was divided between
the country and the principal towns. The greater part of it
was laid upon the country; and of what was laid upon the towns,
the greater part was assessed upon the houses. What remained
to be assessed upon the stock or trade of the towns (for the
stock upon the land was not meant to be taxed) was very much
below the real value of that stock or trade. Whatever inequalities,
therefore, there might be in the original assessment gave little
disturbance. Every parish and district still continues to be
rated for its land, its houses, and its stock, according to
the original assessment; and the almost universal prosperity
of the country, which in most places has raised very much the
value of all these, has rendered those inequalities of still
less importance now. The rate, too, upon each district continuing
always the same, the uncertainty of this tax so far as it might
be assessed upon the stock of any individual, has been very
much diminished, as well as rendered of much less consequence.
If the greater part of the lands of England are not rated to
the land-tax at half their actual value, the greater part of
the stock of England is, perhaps, scarce rated at the fiftieth
part of its actual value. In some towns the whole land-tax
is assessed upon houses, as in Westminster, where stock and
trade are free. It is otherwise in London.
In all countries a severe inquisition into the circumstances
of private persons has been carefully avoided.
At Hamburg every inhabitant is obliged to pay to the state
one-fourth per cent of all that he possesses; and as the wealth
of the people of Hamburg consists principally in stock, this
tax may be considered as a tax upon stock. Every man assesses
himself, and, in the presence of the magistrate, puts annually
into the public coffer a certain sum of money which he declares
upon oath to be one-fourth per cent of all that he possesses,
but without declaring what it amounts to, or being liable to
any examination upon that subject. This tax is generally supposed
to be paid with great fidelity. In a small republic, where
the people have entire confidence in their magistrates, are
convinced of the necessity of the tax for the support of the
state, and believe that it will be faithfully applied to that
purpose, such conscientious and voluntary payment may sometimes
be expected. It is not peculiar to the people of Hamburg.
The canton of Unterwald in Switzerland is frequently ravaged
by storms and inundations, and is thereby exposed to extraordinary
expenses. Upon such occasions the people assemble, and every
one is said to declare with the greatest frankness what he
is worth in order to be taxed accordingly. At Zurich the law
orders that, in cases of necessity, every one should be taxed
in proportion to his revenue- the amount of which he is obliged
to declare upon oath. They have no suspicion, it is said, that
any of their fellow-citizens will deceive them. At Basel the
principal revenue of the state arises from a small custom upon
goods exported. All the citizens make oath that they will pay
every three months all the taxes imposed by the law. All merchants
and even all innkeepers are trusted with keeping themselves
the account of the goods which they sell either within or without
the territory. At the end of every three months they send this
account to the treasurer with the amount of the tax computed
at the bottom of it. It is not suspected that the revenue suffers
by this confidence.
To oblige every citizen to declare publicly upon oath the
amount of his fortune must not, it seems, in those Swiss cantons
be reckoned a hardship. At Hamburg it would be reckoned the
greatest. Merchants engaged in the hazardous protects of trade
all tremble at the thoughts of being obliged at all to expose
the real state of their circumstances. The ruin of their credit
and the miscarriage of their projects, they foresee, would
too often be the consequence. A sober and parsimonious people,
who are strangers to all such projects, do not feel that they
have occasion for any such concealment.
In Holland, soon after the exaltation of the late Prince of
Orange to the stadtholdership, a tax of two per cent, or the
fiftieth penny, as it was called, was imposed upon the whole
substance of every citizen. Every citizen assessed himself
and paid his tax in the same manner as at Hamburg, and it was
in general supposed to have been paid with great fidelity.
The people had at that time the greatest affection for their
new government, which they had just established by a general
insurrection. The tax was to be paid but once, in order to
relieve the state in a particular exigency. It was, indeed,
too heavy to be permanent. In a country where the market rate
of interest seldom exceeds three per cent, a tax of two per
cent amounts to thirteen shillings and fourpence in the pound
upon the highest net revenue which is commonly drawn from stock.
It is a tax which very few people could pay without encroaching
more or less upon their capitals. In a particular exigency
the people may, from great public zeal, make a great effort,
and give up even a part of their capital in order to relieve
the state. But it is impossible that they should continue to
do so for any considerable time; and if they did, the tax would
ruin them so completely as to render them altogether incapable
of supporting the state.
The tax upon stock imposed by the Land-tax Bill in England,
though it is proportioned to the capital, is not intended to
diminish or take away any part of that capital. It is meant
only to be a tax upon the interest of money proportioned to
that upon the rent of land, so that when the latter is at four
shillings in the pound, the former may be at four shillings
in the pound too. The tax at Hamburg and the still more moderate
tax of Unterwald and Zurich are meant, in the same manner,
to be taxes, not upon the capital, but upon the interest or
net revenue of stock. That of Holland was meant to be a tax
upon the capital.
Taxes upon as Profit of particular Employments
In some countries extraordinary taxes are imposed upon the profits
of stock, sometimes when employed in particular branches of trade,
and sometimes when employed in
agriculture.
Of the former kind are in England the tax upon hawkers and
pedlars, that upon hackney coaches and chairs, and that which
the keepers of ale-houses pay for a licence to retail ale and
spirituous liquors. During the late war, another tax of the
same kind was proposed upon shops. The war having been undertaken,
it was said, in defence of the trade of the country, the merchants,
who were to profit by it, ought to contribute towards the support
of it.
A tax, however, upon the profits of stock employed in any
particular branch of trade can never fall finally upon the
dealers (who must in all ordinary cases have their reasonable
profit, and where the competition is free can seldom have more
than that profit), but always upon the consumers, who must
be obliged to pay in the price of the goods the tax which the
dealer advances; and generally with some overcharge.
A tax of this kind when it is proportioned to the trade of
the dealer is finally paid by the consumer, and occasions no
oppression to the dealer. When it is not so proportioned, but
is the same upon all dealers, though in this case, too, it
is finally paid by the consumer, yet it favours the great,
and occasions some oppression to the small dealer. The tax
of five shillings a week upon every hackney coach, and that
of ten shillings a year upon every hackney chair, so far as
it is advanced by the different keepers of such coaches and
chairs, is exactly enough proportioned to the extent of their
respective dealings. It neither favours the great, nor oppresses
the smaller dealer. The tax of twenty shillings a year for
a licence to sell ale; of forty shillings for a licence to
sell spirituous liquors; and of forty shillings more for a
licence to sell wine, being the same upon all retailers, must
necessarily give some advantage to the great, and occasion
some oppression to the small dealers. The former must find
it more easy to get back the tax in the price of their goods
than the latter. The moderation of the tax, however, renders
this inequality of less importance, and it may to many people
appear not improper to give some discouragement to the multiplication
of little ale-houses. The tax upon shops, it was intended,
should be the same upon all shops. It could not well have been
otherwise. It would have been impossible to proportion with
tolerable exactness the tax upon a shop to the extent of the
trade carried on in it without such an inquisition as would
have been altogether insupportable in a free country. If the
tax had been considerable, it would have oppressed the small,
and forced almost the whole retail trade into the hands of
the great dealers. The competition of the former being taken
away, the latter would have enjoyed a monopoly of the trade,
and like all other monopolists would soon have combined to
raise their profits much beyond what was necessary for the
payment of the tax. The final payment, instead of falling upon
the shopkeeper, would have fallen upon the consumer, with a
considerable overcharge to the profit of the shopkeeper. For
these reasons the project of a tax upon shops was laid aside,
and in the room of it was substituted the subsidy, 1759.
What in France is called the personal taille is, perhaps,
the most important tax upon the profits of stock employed in
agriculture that is levied in any part of Europe.
In the disorderly state of Europe during the prevalence of
the feudal government, the sovereign was obliged to content
himself with taxing those who were too weak to refuse to pay
taxes. The great lords, though willing to assist him upon particular
emergencies, refused to subject themselves to any constant
tax, and he was not strong enough to force them. The occupiers
of land all over Europe were, the greater part of them, originally
bondmen. Through the greater part of Europe they were gradually
emancipated. Some of them acquired the property of landed estates
which they held by some base or ignoble tenure, sometimes under
the king, and sometimes under some other great lord, like the
ancient copy-holders of England. Others without acquiring the
property, obtained leases for terms of years of the lands which
they occupied under their lord, and thus became less dependent
upon him. The great lords seem to have beheld the degree of
prosperity and independency which this inferior order of men
had thus come to enjoy with a malignant and contemptuous indignation,
and willingly consented that the sovereign should tax them.
In some countries this tax was confined to the lands which
were held in property by an ignoble tenure; and, in this case,
the taille was said to be real. The land-tax established by
the late King of Sardinia, and the taille in the provinces
of Languedoc, Provence, Dauphine, and Brittany, in the generality
of Montauban, and in the elections of Agen and Comdom, as well
as in some other districts of France, are taxes upon lands
held in property by an ignoble tenure. In other countries the
tax was laid upon the supposed profits of all those who held
in farm or lease lands belonging to other people, whatever
might be the tenure by which the proprietor held them; and
in this case the taille was said to be personal. In the greater
part of those provinces of France which are called the Countries
of Elections the taille is of this kind. The real taille, as
it is imposed only upon a part of the lands of the country,
is necessarily an unequal, but it is not always an arbitrary
tax, though it is so upon some occasions. The personal taille,
as it is intended to be proportioned to the profits of a certain
class of people which can only be guessed at, is necessarily
both arbitrary and unequal.
In France the personal taille at present (1775) annually imposed
upon the twenty generalities called the Countries of Elections
amounts to 40,107,239 livres, 16 sous. The proportion in which
this sum is assessed upon those different provinces varies
from year to year according to the reports which are made to
the king's council concerning the goodness or badness of the
crops, as well as other circumstances which may either increase
or diminish their respective abilities to pay. Each generality
it divided into a certain number of elections, and the proportion
in which the sum imposed upon the whole generality is divided
among those different elections varies likewise from year to
year according to the reports made to the council concerning
their respective abilities. It seems impossible that the council,
with the best intentions, can ever proportion with tolerable
exactness either of those two assessments to the real abilities
of the province or district upon which they are respectively
laid. Ignorance and misinformation must always, more or less,
mislead the most upright council. The proportion which each
parish ought to support of what is assessed upon the whole
election, and that which each individual ought to support of
what is assessed upon his particular parish, are both in the
same manner varied, from year to year, according as circumstances
are supposed to require. These circumstances are judged of,
in the one case, by the officers of the election, in the other
by those of the parish, and both the one and the other are,
more or less, under the direction and influence of the intendant.
Not only ignorance and misinformation, but friendship, party
animosity, and private resentment are said frequently to mislead
such assessors. No man subject to such a tax, it is evident,
can ever be certain, before he is assessed, of what he is to
pay. He cannot even be certain after he is assessed. If any
person has been taxed who ought to have been exempted, or if
any person has been taxed beyond his proportion, though both
must pay in the meantime, yet if they complain, and make good
their complaints, the whole parish is reimposed next year in
order to reimburse them. If any of the contributors become
bankrupt or insolvent, the collector is obliged to advance
his tax, and the whole parish is reimposed next year in order
to reimburse the collector. If the collector himself should
become bankrupt, the parish which elects him must answer for
his conduct to the receiver general of the election. But, as
it might be troublesome for the receiver to prosecute the whole
parish, he takes at his choice five or six of the richest contributors
and obliges them to make good what had been lost by the insolvency
of the collector. The parish is afterwards reimposed in order
to reimburse those five or six. Such reimpositions are always
over and above the taille of the particular year in which they
are laid on.
When a tax is imposed upon the profits of stock in a particular
branch of trade, the traders are all careful to bring no more
goods to market than what they can sell at a price sufficient
to reimburse them for advancing the tax. Some of them withdraw
a part of their stocks from the trade, and the market is more
sparingly supplied than before. The price of the goods rises,
and the final payment of the tax falls upon the consumer. But
when a tax is imposed upon the profits of stock employed in
agriculture, it is not the interest of the farmers to withdraw
any part of their stock from that employment. Each farmer occupies
a certain quantity of land, for which hi pays rent. For the
proper cultivation of this land a certain quantity of stock
is necessary, and by withdrawing any part of this necessary
quantity, the farmer is not likely to be more able to pay either
the rent or the tax. In order to pay the tax, it can never
be his interest to diminish the quantity of his produce, nor
consequently to supply the market more sparingly than before.
The tax, therefore, will never enable him to raise the price
of his produce so as to reimburse himself by throwing the final
payment upon the consumer. The farmer, however, must have his
reasonable profit as well as every other dealer, otherwise
he must give up the trade. After the imposition of a tax of
this kind, he can get this reasonable profit only by paying
less rent to the landlord. The more he is obliged to pay in
the way of tax the less he can afford to pay in the way of
rent. A tax of this kind imposed during the currency of a lease
may, no doubt, distress or ruin the farmer. Upon the renewal
of the lease it must always fall upon the landlord.
In the countries where the personal taille takes place, the
farmer is commonly assessed in proportion to the stock which
he appears to employ in cultivation. He is, upon this account,
frequently afraid to have a good team of horses or oxen, but
endeavours to cultivate with the meanest and most wretched
instruments of husbandry that he can. Such is his distrust
in the justice of his assessors that he counterfeits poverty,
and wishes to appear scarce able to pay anything for fear of
being obliged to pay too much. By this miserable policy he
does not, perhaps, always consult his own interest in the most
effectual manner, and he probably loses more by the diminution
of his produce than he saves by that of his tax. Though, in
consequence of this wretched cultivation, the market is, no
doubt, somewhat worse supplied, yet the small rise of price
which may occasion, as it is not likely even to indemnify the
farmer for the diminution of his produce, it is still less
likely to enable him to pay more rent to the landlord. The
public, the farmer, the landlord, all suffer more or less by
this degraded cultivation. That the personal taille tends,
in many different ways, to discourage cultivation, and consequently
to dry up the principal source of the wealth of every great
country, I have already had occasion to observe in the third
book of this Inquiry.
What are called poll-taxes in the southern provinces of North
America, and in the West Indian Islands annual taxes of so
much a head upon every negro, are properly taxes upon the profits
of a certain species of stock employed in agriculture. As the
planters are, the greater part of them, both farmers and landlords,
the final payment of the tax falls upon them in their quality
of landlords without any retribution.
Taxes of so much a head upon the bondmen employed in cultivation
seem anciently to have been common all over Europe. There subsists
at present a tax of this kind in the empire of Russia. It is
probably upon this account that poll-taxes of all kinds have
often been represented as badges of slavery. Every tax, however,
is to the person who pays it a badge, not of slavery, but of
liberty. It denotes that he is subject to government, indeed,
but that, as he has some property, he cannot himself be the
property of a master. A poll-tax upon slaves is altogether
different from a poll-tax upon freemen. The latter is paid
by the persons upon whom it is imposed; the former by a different
set of persons. The latter is either altogether arbitrary or
altogether unequal, and in most cases is both the one and the
other; the former, though in some respects unequal, different
slaves being of different values, is in no respect arbitrary.
Every master who knows the number of his own slaves knows exactly
what he has to pay. Those different taxes, however, being called
by the same name, have been considered as of the same nature.
The taxes which in Holland are imposed upon men- and maid-servants
are taxes, not upon stock, but upon expense, and so far resemble
the taxes upon consumable commodities. The tax of a guinea
a head for every man-servant which has lately been imposed
in Great Britain is of the same kind. It falls heaviest upon
the middling rank. A man of two hundred a year may keep a single
manservant. A man of ten thousand a year will not keep fifty.
It does not affect the poor.
Taxes upon the profits of stock in particular employments
can never affect the interest of money. Nobody will lend his
money for less interest to those who exercise the taxed than
to those who exercise the untaxed employments. Taxes upon the
revenue arising from stock in all employments where the government
attempts to levy them with any degree of exactness, will, in
many cases, fall upon the interest of money. The Vingtieme,
or twentieth penny, in France is a tax of the same kind with
what is called the land-tax in England, and is assessed, in
the same manner, upon the revenue arising from land, houses,
and stock. So far as it affects stock it is assessed, though
not with great rigour, yet with much more exactness than that
part of the land-tax of England which is imposed upon the same
fund. It, in many cases, falls altogether upon the interest
of money. Money is frequently sunk in France upon what are
called Contracts for the constitution of a rent; that is, perpetual
annuities redeemable at any time by the debtor upon repayment
of the sum originally advanced, but of which this redemption
is not exigible by the creditor except in particular cases.
The Vingtieme, seems not to have raised the rate of those annuities,
though it is exactly levied upon them all.
Appendix to Articles I and II.
Taxes upon the Capital Value of Land,
Houses, and Stock
While property remains in the possession of the same person,
whatever permanent taxes may have been imposed upon it, they
have never been intended to diminish or take away any part
of its capital value, but only some part of the revenue arising
from it. But when property changes hands, when it is transmitted
either from the dead to the living, or from the living to the
living, such taxes have frequently been imposed upon it as
necessarily take away some part of its capital value.
The transference of all sorts of property from the dead to
the living, and that of immovable property, of lands and houses,
from the living to the living, are transactions which are in
their nature either public and notorious, or such as cannot
be long concealed. Such transactions, therefore, may be taxed
directly. The transference of stock, or movable property, from
the living to the living, by the lending of money, is frequently
a secret transaction, and may always be made so. It cannot
easily, therefore, be taxed directly. It has been taxed indirectly
in two different ways; first, by requiring that the deed containing
the obligation to repay should be written upon paper or parchment
which had paid a certain stamp-duty, otherwise not to be valid;
secondly, by requiring, under the like penalty of invalidity,
that it should be recorded either in a public or secret register,
and by imposing certain duties upon such registration. Stamp-duties
and duties of registration have frequently been imposed likewise
upon the deeds transferring property of all kinds from the
dead to the living, and upon those transferring immovable property
from the living to the living, transactions which might easily
have been taxed directly.
The Vicesima Hereditatum, the twentieth penny of inheritances
imposed by Augustus upon the ancient Romans, was a tax upon
the transference of property from the dead to the living. Dion
Cassius, the author who writes concerning it the least indistinctly,
says that it was imposed upon all successions, legacies, and
donations in case of death, except upon those to the nearest
relations and to the poor.
Of the same kind is the Dutch tax upon successions. Collateral
successions are taxed, according to the degree of relation,
from five to thirty per cent upon the whole value of the succession.
Testamentary donations, or legacies to collaterals, are subject
to the like duties. Those from husband to wife, or from wife
to husband, to the fiftieth penny. The Luctuosa Hereditas,
the mournful succession of ascendants to descendants, to the
twentieth penny only. Direct successions, or those of descendants
to ascendants, pay no tax. The death of a father, to such of
his children as live in the same house with him, is seldom
attended with any increase, and frequently with a considerable
diminution of revenue, by the loss of his industry, of his
office, or of some life-rent estate of which he may have been
in possession. That tax would be cruel and oppressive which
aggravated their loss by taking from them any part of his succession.
It may, however, sometimes be otherwise with those children
who, in the language of the Roman law, are said to be emancipated;
in that of the Scotch law, to be forisfamiliated; that is,
who have received their portion, have got families of their
own, and are supported by funds separate and independent of
those of their father. Whatever part of his succession might
come to such children would be a real addition to their fortune,
and might therefore, perhaps, without more inconveniency than
what attends all duties of this kind, be liable to some tax.
The casualties of the feudal law were taxes upon the transference
of land, both from the dead to the living, and from the living
to the living. In ancient times they constituted in every part
of Europe one of the principal branches of the revenue of the
crown.
The heir of every immediate vassal of the crown paid a certain
duty, generally a year's rent, upon receiving the investiture
of the estate. If the heir was a minor, the whole rents of
the estate during the continuance of the minority devolved
to the superior without any other charge besides the maintenance
of the minor, and the payment of the widow's dower when there
happened to be a dowager upon the land. When the minor came
to be of age, another tax, called Relief, was still due to
the superior, which generally amounted likewise to a year's
rent. A long minority, which in the present times so frequently
disburdens a great estate of all its incumbrances and restores
the family to their ancient splendour, could in those times
have no such effect. The waste, and not the disincumbrance
of the estate, was the common effect of a long minority.
By the feudal law the vassal could not alienate without the
consent of his superior, who generally extorted a fine or composition
for granting it. This fine, which was at first arbitrary, came
in many countries to be regulated at a certain portion of the
price of the land. In some countries where the greater part
of the other feudal customs have gone into disuse, this tax
upon the alienation of land still continues to make a very
considerable branch of the revenue of the sovereign. In the
canton of Berne it is so high as a sixth part of the price
of all noble fiefs, and a tenth part of that of all ignoble
ones. In the canton of Lucerne the tax upon the sale of lands
is not universal, and takes place only in certain districts.
But if any person sells his land in order to remove out of
the territory, he pays ten per cent upon the whole price of
the sale. Taxes of the same kind upon the sale either of all
lands, or of lands held by certain tenures, take place in many
other countries, and make a more or less considerable branch
of the revenue of the sovereign.
Such transactions may be taxed indirectly by means either
of stamp-duties, or of duties upon registration, and those
duties either may or may not be proportioned to the value of
the subject which is transferred.
In Great Britain the stamp-duties are higher or lower, not
so much according to the value of the property transferred
(an eighteenpenny or half-crown stamp being sufficient upon
a bond for the largest sum of money) as according to the nature
of the deed. The highest do not exceed six pounds upon every
sheet of paper or skin of parchment, and these high duties
fall chiefly upon grants from the crown, and upon certain law
proceedings, without any regard to the value of the subject.
There are in Great Britain no duties on the registration of
deeds or writings, except the fees of the officers who keep
the register, and these are seldom more than a reasonable recompense
for their labour. The crown derives no revenue from them.
In Holland there are both stamp-duties and duties upon registration,
which in some cases are, and in some are not, proportioned
to the value of the property transferred. All testaments must
be written upon stamped paper of which the price is proportioned
to the property disposed of, so that there are stamps which
cost from threepence, or three stivers a sheet, to three hundred
florins, equal to about twenty-seven pounds ten shillings of
our money. If the stamp is of an inferior price to what the
testator ought to have made use of, his succession is confiscated.
This is over and above all their other taxes on succession.
Except bills of exchange, and some other mercantile bills,
all other deeds, bonds, and contracts are subject to a stamp-duty.
This duty, however, does not rise in proportion to the value
of the subject. All sales of land and of houses, and all mortgages
upon either, must be registered, and, upon registration, pay
a duty to the state of two and a half per cent upon the amount
of the price or of the mortgage. This duty is extended to the
sale of all ships and vessels of more than two tons burden,
whether decked or undecked. These, it seems, are considered
as a sort of houses upon the water. The sale of movables, when
it is ordered by a court of justice, is subject to the like
duty of two and a half per cent.
In France there are both stamp-duties and duties upon registration.
The former are considered as a branch of the aides or excise,
and in the provinces where those duties take place are levied
by the excise officers. The latter are considered as a branch
of the domain of the crown, and are levied by a different set
of officers.
Those modes of taxation, by stamp-duties and by duties upon
registration, are of very modern invention. In the course of
little more than a century, however, stamp-duties have, in
Europe, become almost universal, and duties upon registration
extremely common. There is no art which one government sooner
learns of another than that of draining money from the pockets
of the people.
Taxes upon the transference of property from the dead to the
living fall finally as well as immediately upon the person
to whom the property is transferred. Taxes upon the sale of
land fall altogether upon the seller. The seller is almost
always under the necessity of selling, and must, therefore,
take such a price as he can get. The buyer is scarce ever under
the necessity of buying, and will, therefore, only give such
a price as he likes. He considers what the land will cost him
in tax and price together. The more he is obliged to pay in
the way of tax, the less he will be disposed to give in the
way of price. Such taxes, therefore, fall almost always upon
a necessitous person, and must, therefore, be frequently very
cruel and oppressive. Taxes upon the sale of new-built houses,
where the building is sold without the ground, fall generally
upon the buyer, because the builder must generally have his
profit, otherwise he must give up the trade. If he advances
the tax, therefore, the buyer must generally repay it to him.
Taxes upon the sale of old houses, for the same reason as those
upon the sale of land, fall generally upon the seller, whom
in most cases either conveniency or necessity obliges to sell.
The number of new-built houses that are annually brought to
market is more or less regulated by the demand. Unless the
demand is such as to afford the builder his profit, after paying
all expenses, he will build no more houses. The number of old
houses which happen at any time to come to market is regulated
by accidents of which the greater part have no relation to
the demand. Two or three great bankruptcies in a mercantile
town will bring many houses to sale which must be sold for
what can be got for them. Taxes upon the sale of ground-rents
fall altogether upon the seller, for the same reason as those
upon the sale of land. Stamp-duties, and duties upon the registration
of bonds and contracts for borrowed money, fall altogether
upon the borrower, and, in fact, are always paid by him. Duties
of the same kind upon law proceedings fall upon the suitors.
They reduce to both the capital value of the subject in dispute.
The more it costs to acquire any property, the less must be
the net value of it when acquired.
All taxes upon the transference of property of every kind,
so far as they diminish the capital value of that property,
tend to diminish the funds destined for the maintenance of
productive labour. They are all more or less unthrifty taxes
that increase the revenue of the sovereign, which seldom maintains
any but unproductive labourers, at the expense of the capital
of the people, which maintains none but productive.
Such taxes, even when they are proportioned to the value of
the property transferred, are still unequal, the frequency
of transference not being always equal in property of equal
value. When they are not proportioned to this value, which
is the case with the greater part of the stamp-duties and duties
of registration, they are still more so. They are in no respect
arbitrary, but are or may be in all cases perfectly clear and
certain. Though they sometimes fall upon the person who is
not very able to pay, the time of payment is in most cases
sufficiently convenient for him. When the payment becomes due,
he must in most cases have the money to pay. They are levied
at very little expense, and in general subject the contributors
to no other inconveniency besides always the unavoidable one
of paying the tax.
In France the stamp-duties are not much complained of. Those
of registration, which they call the Controle, are. They give
occasion, it is pretended, to much extortion in the officers
of the farmers-general who collect the tax, which is in a great
measure arbitrary and uncertain. In the greater part of the
libels which have been written against the present system of
finances in France the abuses of the Controle make a principal
article. Uncertainty, however, does not seem to be necessarily
inherent in the nature of such taxes. If the popular complaints
are well founded, the abuse must arise, not so much from the
nature of the tax as from the want of precision and distinctness
in the words of the edicts or laws which impose it.
The registration of mortgages, and in general of all rights
upon immovable property, as it gives great security both to
creditors and purchasers, is extremely advantageous to the
public. That of the greater part of deeds of other kinds is
frequently inconvenient and even dangerous to individuals,
without any advantage to the public. All registers which, it
is acknowledged, ought to be kept secret, ought certainly never
to exist. The credit of individuals ought certainly never to
depend upon so very slender a security as the probity and religion
of the inferior officers of revenue. But where the fees of
registration have been made a source of revenue to the sovereign,
register offices have commonly been multiplied without end,
both for the deeds which ought to be registered, and for those
which ought not. In France there are several different sorts
of secret registers. This abuse, though not perhaps a necessary,
it must be acknowledged, is a very natural effect of such taxes.
Such stamp-duties as those in England upon cards and dice,
upon newspapers and periodical pamphlets, etc., are properly
taxes upon consumption; the final payment falls upon the persons
who use or consume such commodities. Such stamp-duties as those
upon licences to retail ale, wine, and spirituous liquors,
though intended, perhaps, to fall upon the profits of the retailers,
are likewise finally paid by the consumers of those liquors.
Such taxes, though called by the same name, and levied by the
same officers and in the same manner with the stamp-duties
above mentioned upon the transference of property, are, however,
of a quite different nature, and fall upon quite different
funds.
Article III
Taxes upon the Wages of Labour
The wages of the inferior classes of workmen, I have endeavoured
to show in the first book, are everywhere necessarily regulated
by two different circumstances; the demand for labour, and the
ordinary or average price of provisions. The demand for labour,
according as it happens to be either increasing, stationary,
or declining, or to require an increasing, stationary, or declining
population, regulates the subsistence of the labourer, and determines
in what degree it shall be, either liberal, moderate, or scanty.
The ordinary or average price of provisions determines the quantity
of money which must be paid to the workman in order to enable
him, one year with another, to purchase this liberal, moderate,
or scanty subsistence. While the demand for labour and the price
of provisions, therefore, remain the same, a direct tax upon
the wages of labour can have no other effect than to raise them
somewhat higher than the tax. Let us suppose, for example, that
in a particular place the demand for labour and the price of
provisions were such as to render ten shillings a week the ordinary
wages of labour, and that a tax of one-fifth, or four shillings
in the pound, was imposed upon wages. If the demand for labour
and the price of provisions remained the same, it would still
be necessary that the labourer should in that place earn such
a subsistence as could be bought only for ten shillings a week
free wages. But in order to leave him such free wages after paying
such a tax, the price of labour must in that place soon rise,
not to twelve shillings a week only, but to twelve and sixpence;
that is, in order to enable him to pay a tax of one-fifth, his
wages must necessarily soon rise, not one-fifth part only, but
one-fourth. Whatever was the proportion of the tax, the wages
of labour must in all cases rise, not only in that proportion,
but in a higher proportion. If the tax, for example, was one-tenth,
the wages of labour must necessarily soon rise, not one-tenth
part only, but one-eighth.
A direct tax upon the wages of labour, therefore, though the
labourer might perhaps pay it out of his hand, could not properly
be said to be even advanced by him; at least if tile demand
for labour and the average price of provisions remained the
same after the tax as before it. In all such cases, not only
the tax but something more than the tax would in reality be
advanced by the person who immediately employed him. The final
payment would in different cases fall upon different persons.
The rise which such a tax might occasion in the wages of manufacturing
labour would be advanced by the master manufacturer, who would
both be entitled and obliged to charge it, with a profit, upon
the price of his goods. The final payment of this rise of wages,
therefore, together with the additional profit of the master
manufacturer, would fall upon the consumer. The rise which
such a tax might occasion in the wages of country labour would
be advanced by the farmer, who, in order to maintain the same
number of labourers as before, would be obliged to employ a
greater capital. In order to get back this greater capital,
together with the ordinary profits of stock, it would be necessary
that he should retain a larger portion, or what comes to the
same thing, the price of a larger portion, of the produce of
the land, and consequently that he should pay less rent to
the landlord. The final payment of this rise of wages, therefore,
would in this case fall upon the landlord, together with the
additional profit of the farmer who had advanced it. In all
cases a direct tax upon the wages of labour must, in the long-run,
occasion both a greater reduction in the rent of land, and
a greater rise in the price of manufactured goods, than would
have followed from the proper assessment of a sum equal to
the produce of the tax partly upon the rent of land, and partly
upon consumable commodities.
If direct taxes upon the wages of labour have not always occasioned
a proportionable rise in those wages, it is because they have
generally occasioned a considerable fall in the demand for
labour. The declension of industry, the decrease of employment
for the poor, the diminution of the annual produce of the land
and labour of the country, have generally been the effects
of such taxes. In consequence of them, however, the price of
labour must always be higher than it otherwise would have been
in the actual state of the demand: and this enhancement of
price, together with the profit of those who advance it, must
always be finally paid by the landlords and consumers.
A tax upon the wages of country labour does not raise the
price of the rude produce of land in proportion to the tax,
for the same reason that a tax upon the farmer's profit does
not raise that price in that proportion.
Absurd and destructive as such taxes are, however, they take
place in many countries. In France that part of the taille
which is charged upon the industry of workmen and day-labourers
in country villages is properly a tax of this kind. Their wages
are computed according to the common rate of the district in
which they reside, and that they may be as little liable as
possible to any overcharge, their yearly gains are estimated
at no more than two hundred working days in the year. The tax
of each individual is varied from year to year according to
different circumstances, of which the collector or the commissary
whom the intendant appoints to assist him are the judges. In
Bohemia, in consequence of the alteration in the system of
finances which was begun in 1748, a very heavy tax is imposed
upon the industry of artificers. They are divided into four
classes. The highest class pay a hundred florins a year which,
at two-and-twenty pence halfpenny a florin, amounts to L9 7s.
6d. The second class are taxed at seventy; the third at fifty;
and the fourth, comprehending artificers in villages, and the
lowest class of those in towns, at twenty-five florins.
The recompense of ingenious artists and of men of liberal
professions, I have endeavoured to show in the first book,
necessarily keeps a certain proportion to the emoluments of
inferior trades. A tax upon this recompense, therefore, could
have no other effect than to raise it somewhat higher than
in proportion to the tax. If it did not rise in this manner,
the ingenious arts and the liberal professions, being no longer
upon a level with other trades, would be so much deserted that
they would soon return to that level.
The emoluments of offices are not, like those of trades and
professions, regulated by the free competition of the market,
and do not, therefore, always bear a just proportion to what
the nature of the employment requires. They are, perhaps, in
most countries, higher than it requires; the persons who have
the administration of government being generally disposed to
reward both themselves and their immediate dependants rather
more than enough. The emoluments of offices, therefore, can
in most cases very well bear to be taxed. The persons, besides,
who enjoy public offices, especially the more lucrative, are
in all countries the objects of general envy, and a tax upon
their emoluments, even though it should be somewhat higher
than upon any other sort of revenue, is always a very popular
tax. In England, for example, when by the land-tax every other
sort of revenue was supposed to be assessed at four shillings
in the pound, it was very popular to lay a real tax of five
shillings and sixpence in the pound upon the salaries of offices
which exceeded a hundred pounds a year, the pensions of the
younger branches of the royal family, the pay of the officers
of the army and navy, and a few others less obnoxious to envy
excepted. There are in England no other direct taxes upon the
wages of labour.
Article
IV: Taxes which, it is intended, should fall indifferently
upon every
different Species of Revenue
The taxes which, it is intended, should fall indifferently upon
every different species of revenue, are capitation taxes, and
taxes upon consumable commodities. These must be paid indifferently
from whatever revenue the contributors may possess; from the
rent of their land, from the profits of their stock, or from
the wages of their
labour.
Capitation Taxes
Capitation taxes, if it is attempted to proportion them to the
fortune or revenue of each contributor, become altogether arbitrary.
The state of a man's fortune varies from day to day, and without
an inquisition more intolerable than any tax, and renewed at
least once every year, can only be guessed at. His assessment,
therefore, must in most cases depend upon the good or bad humour
of his assessors, and must, therefore, be altogether arbitrary
and
uncertain.
Capitation taxes, if they are proportioned not to the supposed
fortune, but to the rank of each contributor, become altogether
unequal, the degrees of fortune being frequently unequal in
the same degree of rank.
Such taxes, therefore, if it is attempted to render them equal,
become altogether arbitrary and uncertain, and if it is attempted
to render them certain and not arbitrary, become altogether
unequal. Let the tax be light or heavy, uncertainty is always
a great grievance. In a light tax a considerable degree of
inequality may be supported; in a heavy one it is altogether
intolerable.
In the different poll-taxes which took place in England during
the reign of William III the contributors were, the greater
part of them, assessed according to the degree of their rank;
as dukes, marquisses, earls, viscounts, barons, esquires, gentlemen,
the eldest and youngest sons of peers, etc. All shopkeepers
and tradesmen worth more than three hundred pounds, that is,
the better sort of them, were subject to the same assessment,
how great soever might be the difference in their fortunes.
Their rank was more considered than their fortune. Several
of those who in the first poll-tax were rated according to
their supposed fortune were afterwards rated according to their
rank. Serjeants, attorneys, and proctors at law, who in the
first poll-tax were assessed at three shillings in the pound
of their supposed income, were afterwards assessed as gentlemen.
In the assessment of a tax which was not very heavy, a considerable
degree of inequality had been found less insupportable than
any degree of uncertainty.
In the capitation which has been levied in France without
any interruption since the beginning of the present century,
the highest orders of people are rated according to their rank
by an invariable tariff; the lower orders of people, according
to what is supposed to be their fortune, by an assessment which
varies from year to year. The officers of the king's court,
the judges and other officers in the superior courts of justice,
the officers of the troops, etc., are assessed in the first
manner. The inferior ranks of people in the provinces are assessed
in the second. In France the great easily submit to a considerable
degree of inequality in a tax which, so far as it affects them,
is not a very heavy one, but could not brook the arbitrary
assessment of an intendant. The inferior ranks of people must,
in that country, suffer patiently the usage which their superiors
think proper to give them.
In England the different poll-taxes never produced the sum
which had been expected from them, or which, it was supposed,
they might have produced, had they been exactly levied. In
France the capitation always produces the sum expected from
it. The mild government of England, when it assessed the different
ranks of people to the poll-tax, contented itself with what
that assessment happened to produce, and required no compensation
for the loss which the state might sustain either by those
who could not pay, or by those who would not pay (for there
were many such), and who, by the indulgent execution of the
law, were not forced to pay. The more severe government of
France assesses upon each generality a certain sum, which the
intendant must find as he can. If any province complains of
being assessed too high, it may, in the assessment of next
year, obtain an abatement proportioned to the overcharge of
the year before. But it must pay in the meantime. The intendant,
in order to be sure of finding the sum assessed upon his generality,
was empowered to assess it in a larger sum that the failure
or inability of some of the contributors might be compensated
by the overcharge of the rest, and till 1765 the fixation of
this surplus assessment was left altogether to his discretion.
In that year, indeed, the council assumed this power to itself.
In the capitation of the provinces, it is observed by the perfectly
well-informed author of the Memoires upon the impositions in
France, the proportion which falls upon the nobility, and upon
those whose privileges exempt them from the taille, is the
least considerable. The largest falls upon those subject to
the taille, who are assessed to the capitation at so much a
pound of what they pay to that other tax.
Capitation taxes, so far as they are levied upon the lower
ranks of people, are direct taxes upon the wages of labour,
and are attended with all the inconveniences of such taxes.
Capitation taxes are levied at little expense, and, where
they are rigorously exacted, afford a very sure revenue to
the state. It is upon this account that in countries where
the ease, comfort, and security of the inferior ranks of people
are little attended to, capitation taxes are very common. It
is in general, however, but a small part of the public revenue
which, in a great empire, has ever been drawn from such taxes,
and the greatest sum which they have ever afforded might always
have been found in some other way much more convenient to the
people.
Taxes upon Consumable Commodities
The impossibility of taxing the people, in proportion to their
revenue, by any capitation, seems to have given occasion to the
invention of taxes upon consumable commodities. The state, not
knowing how to tax, directly and proportionably, the revenue
of its subjects, endeavours to tax it indirectly by taxing their
expense, which, it is supposed, will in most cases be nearly
in proportion to their revenue. Their expense is taxed by taxing
the consumable commodities upon which it is laid out.
Consumable commodities are either necessaries or luxuries.
By necessaries I understand not only the commodities which
are indispensably necessary for the support of life, but whatever
the custom of the country renders it indecent for creditable
people, even of the lowest order, to be without. A linen shirt,
for example, is, strictly speaking, not a necessary of life.
The Greeks and Romans lived, I suppose, very comfortably though
they had no linen. But in the present times, through the greater
part of Europe, a creditable day-labourer would be ashamed
to appear in public without a linen shirt, the want of which
would be supposed to denote that disgraceful degree of poverty
which, it is presumed, nobody can well fall into without extreme
bad conduct. Custom, in the same manner, has rendered leather
shoes a necessary of life in England. The poorest creditable
person of either sex would be ashamed to appear in public without
them. In Scotland, custom has rendered them a necessary of
life to the lowest order of men; but not to the same order
of women, who may, without any discredit, walk about barefooted.
In France they are necessaries neither to men nor to women,
the lowest rank of both sexes appearing there publicly, without
any discredit, sometimes in wooden shoes, and sometimes barefooted.
Under necessaries, therefore, I comprehend not only those things
which nature, but those things which the established rules
of decency have rendered necessary to the lowest rank of people.
All other things I call luxuries, without meaning by this appellation
to throw the smallest degree of reproach upon the temperate
use of them. Beer and ale, for example, in Great Britain, and
wine, even in the wine countries, I call luxuries. A man of
any rank may, without any reproach, abstain totally from tasting
such liquors. Nature does not render them necessary for the
support of life, and custom nowhere renders it indecent to
live without them.
As the wages of labour are everywhere regulated, partly by
the demand for it, and partly by the average price of the necessary
articles of subsistence, whatever raises this average price
must necessarily raise those wages so that the labourer may
still be able to purchase that quantity of those necessary
articles which the state of the demand for labour, whether
increasing, stationary, or declining, requires that he should
have. A tax upon those articles necessarily raises their price
somewhat higher than the amount of the tax, because the dealer,
who advances the tax, must generally get it back with a profit.
Such a tax must, therefore, occasion a rise in the wages of
labour proportionable to this rise of price.
It is thus that a tax upon the necessaries of life operates
exactly in the same manner as a direct tax upon the wages of
labour. The labourer, though he may pay it out of his hand,
cannot, for any considerable time at least, be properly said
even to advance it. It must always in the long-run be advanced
to him by his immediate employer in the advanced rate of his
wages. His employer, if he is a manufacturer, will charge upon
the price of his goods this rise of wages, together with a
profit; so that the final payment of the tax, together with
this overcharge, will fall upon the consumer. If his employer
is a farmer, the final payment, together with a like overcharge,
will fall upon the rent of the landlord.
It is otherwise with taxes upon what I call luxuries, even
upon those of the poor. The rise in the price of the taxed
commodities will not necessarily occasion any rise in the wages
of labour. A tax upon tobacco, for example, though a luxury
of the poor as well as of the rich, will not raise wages. Though
it is taxed in England at three times, and in France at fifteen
times its original price, those high duties seem to have no
effect upon the wages of labour. The same thing may be said
of the taxes upon tea and sugar, which in England and Holland
have become luxuries of the lowest ranks of people, and of
those upon chocolate, which in Spain is said to have become
so. The different taxes which in Great Britain have in the
course of the present century been imposed upon spirituous
liquors are not supposed to have had any effect upon the wages
of labour. The rise in the price of porter, occasioned by an
additional tax of three shillings upon the barrel of strong
beer, has not raised the wages of common labour in London.
These were about eighteen pence and twenty pence a day before
the tax, and they are not more now.
The high price of such commodities does not necessarily diminish
the ability of the inferior ranks of people to bring up families.
Upon the sober and industrious poor, taxes upon such commodities
act as sumptuary laws, and dispose them either to moderate,
or to refrain altogether from the use of superfluities which
they can no longer easily afford. Their ability to bring up
families, in consequence of this forced frugality, instead
of being diminished, is frequently, perhaps, increased by the
tax. It is the sober and industrious poor who generally bring
up the most numerous families, and who principally supply the
demand for useful labour. All the poor, indeed, are not sober
and industrious, and the dissolute and disorderly might continue
to indulge themselves in the use of such commodities after
this rise of price in the same manner as before without regarding
the distress which this indulgence might bring upon their families.
Such disorderly persons, however, seldom rear up numerous families,
their children generally perishing from neglect, mismanagement,
and the scantiness or unwholesomeness of their food. If by
the strength of their constitution they survive the hardships
to which the bad conduct of their parents exposes them, yet
the example of that bad conduct commonly corrupts their morals,
so that, instead of being useful to society by their industry,
they become public nuisances by their vices and disorders.
Though the advanced price of the luxuries of the poor, therefore,
might increase somewhat the distress of such disorderly families,
and thereby diminish somewhat their ability to bring up children,
it would not probably diminish much the useful population of
the country.
Any rise in the average price of necessaries, unless it is
compensated by a proportionable rise in the wages of labour,
must necessarily diminish more or less the ability of the poor
to bring up numerous families, and consequently to supply the
demand for useful labour, whatever may be the state of that
demand, whether increasing, stationary, or declining, or such
as requires an increasing, stationary, or declining population.
Taxes upon luxuries have no tendency to raise the price of
any other commodities except that of the commodities taxed.
Taxes upon necessaries, by raising the wages of labour, necessarily
tend to raise the price of all manufactures, and consequently
to diminish the extent of their sale and consumption. Taxes
upon luxuries are finally paid by the consumers of the commodities
taxed without any retribution. They fall indifferently upon
every species of revenue, the wages of labour, the profits
of stock, and the rent of land. Taxes upon necessaries, so
far as they affect the labouring poor, are finally paid, partly
by landlords in the diminished rent of their lands, and partly
by rich consumers, whether landlords or others, in the advanced
price of manufactured goods, and always with a considerable
overcharge. The advanced price of such manufactures as are
real necessaries of life, and are destined for the consumption
of the poor, of coarse woollens, for example, must be compensated
to the poor by a further advancement of their wages. The middling
and superior ranks of people, if they understand their own
interest, ought always to oppose all taxes upon the necessaries
of life, as well as all direct taxes upon the wages of labour.
The final payment of both the one and the other falls altogether
upon themselves, and always with a considerable overcharge.
They fall heaviest upon the landlords, who always pay in a
double capacity; in that of landlords by the reduction of their
rent, and in that of rich consumers by the increase of their
expense. The observation of Sir Matthew Decker, that certain
taxes are, in the price of certain goods, sometimes repeated
and accumulated four or five times, is perfectly just with
regard to taxes upon the necessaries of life. In the price
of leather, for example, you must pay not only for the tax
upon the leather of your own shoes, but for a part of that
upon those of the shoemaker and the tanner. You must pay, too,
for the tax upon the salt, upon the soap, and upon the candles
which those workmen consume while employed in your service,
and for the tax upon the leather which the salt-maker, the
soap-maker, and the candle-maker consume while employed in
their service.
In Great Britain, the principal taxes upon the necessaries
of life are those upon the four commodities just now mentioned,
salt, leather, soap, and candles.
Salt is a very ancient and a very universal subject of taxation.
It was taxed among the Romans, and it is so at present in,
I believe, every part of Europe. The quantity annually consumed
by any individual is so small, and may be purchased so gradually,
that nobody, it seems to have been thought, could feel very
sensibly even a pretty heavy tax upon it. It is in England
taxed at three shillings and fourpence a bushel- about three
times the original price of the commodity. In some other countries
the tax is still higher. Leather is a real necessary of life.
The use of linen renders soap such. In countries where the
winter nights are long, candles are a necessary instrument
of trade. Leather and soap are in Great Britain taxed at three
halfpence a pound, candles at a penny; taxes which, upon the
original price of leather, may amount to about eight or ten
per cent; upon that of soap to about twenty or five-and-twenty
per cent; and upon that of candles to about fourteen or fifteen
per cent; taxes which, though lighter than that upon salt,
are still very heavy. As all those four commodities are real
necessaries of life, such heavy taxes upon them must increase
somewhat the expense of the sober and industrious poor, and
must consequently raise more or less the wages of their labour.
In a country where the winters are so cold as in Great Britain,
fuel is, during that season, in the strictest sense of the
word, a necessary of life, not only for the purpose of dressing
victuals, but for the comfortable subsistence of many different
sorts of workmen who work within doors; and coals are the cheapest
of all fuel. The price of fuel has so important an influence
upon that of labour that all over Great Britain manufactures
have confined themselves principally to the coal countries,
other parts of the country, on account of the high price of
this necessary article, not being able to work so cheap. In
some manufactures, besides, coal is a necessary instrument
of trade, as in those of glass, iron, and all other metals.
If a bounty could in any case be reasonable, it might perhaps
be so upon the transportation of coals from those parts of
the country in which they abound to those in which they are
wanted. But the legislature, instead of a bounty, has imposed
a tax of three shillings and threepence a ton upon coal carried
coastways, which upon most sorts of coal is more than sixty
per cent of the original price at the coal-pit. Coals carried
either by land or by inland navigation pay no duty. Where they
are naturally cheap, they are consumed duty free: where they
are naturally dear, they are loaded with a heavy duty.
Such taxes, though they raise the price of subsistence, and
consequently the wages of labour, yet they afford a considerable
revenue to government which it might not be easy to find in
any other way. There may, therefore, be good reasons for continuing
them. The bounty upon the exportation of corn, so far as it
tends in the actual state of tillage to raise the price of
that necessary article, produces all the like bad effects,
and instead of affording any revenue, frequently occasions
a very great expense to government. The high duties upon the
importation of foreign corn, which in years of moderate plenty
amount to a prohibition, and the absolute prohibition of the
importation either of live cattle or of salt provisions, which
takes place in the ordinary state of the law, and which, on
account of the scarcity, is at present suspended for a limited
time with regard to Ireland and the British plantations, have
all the bad effects of taxes upon the necessaries of life,
and produce no revenue to government. Nothing seems necessary
for the repeal of such regulations but to convince the public
of the futility of that system in consequence of which they
have been established.
Taxes upon the necessaries of life are much higher in many
other countries than in Great Britain. Duties upon flour and
meal when ground at the mill, and upon bread when baked at
the oven, take place in many countries. In Holland the money
price of the bread consumed in towns is supposed to be doubled
by means of such taxes. In lieu of a part of them, the people
who live in the country pay every year so much a head according
to the sort of bread they are supposed to consume. Those who
consume wheaten bread pay three guilders fifteen stivers- about
six shillings and ninepence halfpenny. These, and some other
taxes of the same kind, by raising the price of labour, are
said to have ruined the greater part of the manufactures of
Holland. Similar taxes, though not quite so heavy, take place
in the Milanese, in the states of Genoa, in the duchy of Modena,
in the duchies of Parma, Placentia, and Guastalla, and in the
ecclesiastical state. A French author of some note has proposed
to reform the finances of his country by substituting in the
room of the greater part of other taxes this most ruinous of
all taxes. There is nothing so absurd, says Cicero, which has
not sometimes been asserted by philosophers.
Taxes upon butchers' meat are still more common than those
upon bread. It may indeed be doubted whether butchers' meat
is anywhere a necessary of life. Grain and other vegetables,
with the help of milk, cheese, and butter, or oil where butter
is not to be had, it is known from experience, can, without
any butchers' meat, afford the most plentiful, the most wholesome,
the most nourishing, and the most invigorating diet. Decency
nowhere requires that any man should eat butchers' meat, as
it in most places requires that he should wear a linen shirt
or a pair of leather shoes.
Consumable commodities, whether necessaries or luxuries, may
be taxed in two different ways. The consumer may either pay
an annual sum on account of his using or consuming goods of
a certain kind, or the goods may be taxed while they remain
in the hands of the dealer, and before they are delivered to
the consumer. The consumable goods which last a considerable
time before they are consumed altogether are most properly
taxed in the one way; those of which the consumption is either
immediate or more speedy, in the other. The coach-tax and plate-tax
are examples of the former method of imposing: the greater
part of the other duties of excise and customs, of the latter.
A coach may, with good management, last ten or twelve years.
It might be taxed, once for all, before it comes out of the
hands of the coachmaker. But it is certainly more convenient
for the buyer to pay four pounds a year for the privilege of
keeping a coach than to pay all at once forty or forty-eight
pounds additional price to the coachmaker, or a sum equivalent
to what the tax is likely to cost him during the time he uses
the same coach. A service of plate, in the same manner, may
last more than a century. It is certainly easier for the consumer
to pay five shillings a year for every hundred ounces of plate,
near one per cent of the value, than to redeem this long annuity
at five-and-twenty or thirty years' purchase, which would enhance
the price at least five-and-twenty or thirty per cent. The
different taxes which affect houses are certainly more conveniently
paid by moderate annual payments than by a heavy tax of equal
value upon the first building or sale of the house.
It was the well-known proposal of Sir Matthew Decker that
all commodities, even those of which the consumption is either
immediate or very speedy, should be taxed in this manner, the
dealer advancing nothing, but the consumer paying a certain
annual sum for the licence to consume certain goods. The object
of his scheme was to promote all the different branches of
foreign trade, particularly the carrying trade, by taking away
all duties upon importation and exportation, and thereby enabling
the merchant to employ his whole capital and credit in the
purchase of goods and the freight of ships, no part of either
being diverted towards the advancing of taxes. The project,
however, of taxing, in this manner, goods of immediate or speedy
consumption seems liable to the four following very important
objections. First, the tax would be more unequal, or not so
well proportioned to the expense and consumption of the different
contributors as in the way in which it is commonly imposed.
The taxes upon ale, wine, and spirituous liquors, which are
advanced by the dealers, are finally paid by the different
consumers exactly in proportion to their respective consumption.
But if the tax were to be paid by purchasing a licence to drink
those liquors, the sober would, in proportion to his consumption,
be taxed much more heavily than the drunken consumer. A family
which exercised great hospitality would be taxed much more
lightly than one who entertained fewer guests. Secondly, this
mode of taxation, by paying for an annual, half-yearly, or
quarterly licence to consume certain goods, would diminish
very much one of the principal conveniences of taxes upon goods
of speedy consumption the piecemeal payment. In the price of
threepence halfpenny, which is at present paid for a pot of
porter, the different taxes upon malt, hops, and beer, together
with the extraordinary profit which the brewer charges for
having advanced them, may perhaps amount to about three halfpence.
If a workman can conveniently spare those three halfpence,
he buys a pot of porter. If he cannot, he contents himself
with a pint, and, as a penny saved is a penny got, he thus
gains a farthing by his temperance. He pays the tax piecemeal
as he can afford to pay it, and when he can afford to pay it,
and every act of payment is perfectly voluntary, and what he
can avoid if he chooses to do so. Thirdly, such taxes would
operate less as sumptuary laws. When the licence was once purchased,
whether the purchaser drank much or drank little, his tax would
be the same. Fourthly, if a workman were to pay all at once,
by yearly, half-yearly, or quarterly payments, a tax equal
to what he at present pays, with little or no inconveniency,
upon all the different pots and pints of porter which he drinks
in any such period of time, the sum might frequently distress
him very much. This mode of taxation, therefore, it seems evident,
could never, without the most grievous oppression, produce
a revenue nearly equal to what is derived from the present
mode without any oppression. In several countries, however,
commodities of an immediate or very speedy consumption are
taxed in this manner. In Holland people pay so much a head
for a licence to drink tea. I have already mentioned a tax
upon bread, which, so far as it is consumed in farm-houses
and country villages, is there levied in the same manner.
The duties of excise are imposed briefly upon goods of home
produce destined for home consumption. They are imposed only
upon a few sorts of goods of the most general use. There can
never be any doubt either concerning the goods which are subject
to those duties, or concerning the particular duty which each
species of goods is subject to. They fall almost altogether
upon what I call luxuries, excepting always the four duties
above mentioned, upon salt soap, leather, candles, and, perhaps,
that upon green glass.
The duties of customs are much more ancient than those of
excise. They seem to have been called customs as denoting customary
payments which had been in use from time immemorial. They appear
to have been originally considered as taxes upon the profits
of merchants. During the barbarous times of feudal anarchy,
merchants, like all the other inhabitants of burghs, were considered
as little better than emancipated bondmen, whose persons were
despised, and whose gains were envied. The great nobility,
who had consented that the king should tallage the profits
of their own tenants, were not unwilling that he should tallage
likewise those of an order of men whom it was much less their
interest to protect. In those ignorant times it was not understood
that the profits of merchants are a subject not taxable directly,
or that the final payment of all such taxes must fall, with
a considerable overcharge, upon the consumers.
The gains of alien merchants were looked upon more unfavourably
than those of English merchants. It was natural, therefore,
that those of the former should be taxed more heavily than
those of the latter. This distinction between the duties upon
aliens and those upon English merchants, which was begun from
ignorance, has been continued from the spirit of monopoly,
or in order to give our own merchants an advantage both in
the home and in the foreign market.
With this distinction, the ancient duties of customs were
imposed equally upon all sorts of goods, necessaries as well
as luxuries, goods exported as well as goods imported. Why
should the dealers in one sort of goods, it seems to have been
thought, be more favoured than those in another? or why should
the merchant exporter be more favoured than the merchant importer?
The ancient customs were divided into three branches. The
first, and perhaps the most ancient of all those duties, was
that upon wool and leather. It seems to have been chiefly or
altogether an exportation duty. When the woollen manufacture
came to be established in England, lest the king should lose
any part of his customs upon wool by the exportation of woollen
cloths, a like duty was imposed upon them. The other two branches
were, first, a duty upon wine, which, being imposed at so much
a ton, was called a tonnage, and, secondly, a duty upon all
other goods, which, being imposed at so much a pound of their
supposed value, was called a poundage. In the forty-seventh
year of Edward III a duty of sixpence in the pound was imposed
upon all goods exported and imported, except wools, wool-fells,
leather, and wines, which were subject to particular duties.
In the fourteenth of Richard II this duty was raised to one
shilling in the pound, but three years afterwards it was again
reduced to sixpence. It was raised to eightpence in the second
year of Henry IV, and in the fourth year of the same prince
to one shilling. From this time to the ninth year of William
III this duty continued at one shilling in the pound. The duties
of tonnage and poundage were generally granted to the king
by one and the same Act of Parliament, and were called the
Subsidy of Tonnage and Poundage. The Subsidy of Poundage having
continued for so long a time at one shining in the pound, or
at five per cent, a subsidy came, in the language of the customs,
to denote a general duty of this kind of five per cent. This
subsidy, which is now called the Old Subsidy, still continues
to be levied according to the book of rates established in
the twelfth of Charles II. The method of ascertaining, by a
book of rates, the value of goods subject to this duty is said
to be older than the time of James I. The New Subsidy imposed
by the ninth and tenth of William III was an additional five
per cent upon the greater part of goods. The One-third and
the Two-third Subsidy made up between them another five per
cent of which they were proportionable parts. The Subsidy of
1747 made a fourth five per cent upon the greater part of goods;
and that of 1759 a fifth upon some particular sorts of goods.
Besides those five subsidies, a great variety of other duties
have occasionally been imposed upon particular sorts of goods,
in order sometimes to relieve the exigencies of the state,
and sometimes to regulate the trade of the country according
to the principles of the mercantile system.
That system has come gradually more and more into fashion.
The Old Subsidy was imposed indifferently upon exportation
as well as importation. The four subsequent subsidies, as well
as the other duties which have been occasionally imposed upon
particular sorts of goods have, with a few exceptions, been
laid altogether upon importation. The greater part of the ancient
duties which had been imposed upon the exportation of the goods
of home produce and manufacture have either been lightened
or taken away altogether. In most cases they have been taken
away. Bounties have even been given upon the exportation of
some of them. Drawbacks too, sometimes of the whole, and, in
most cases, of a part of the duties which are paid upon the
importation of foreign goods, have been granted upon their
exportation. Only half the duties imposed by the Old Subsidy
upon importation are drawn back upon exportation: but the whole
of those imposed by the latter subsidies and other imposts
are, upon the greater part of goods, drawn back in the same
manner. This growing favour of exportation, and discouragement
of importation, have suffered only a few exceptions, which
chiefly concern the materials of some manufactures. These our
merchants and manufacturers are willing should come as cheap
as possible to themselves, and as dear as possible to their
rivals and competitors in other countries. Foreign materials
are, upon this account, sometimes allowed to be imported duty
free; Spanish wool, for example, flax, and raw linen yarn.
The exportation of the materials of home produce, and of those
which are the particular produce of our colonies, has sometimes
been prohibited, and sometimes subjected to higher duties.
The exportation of English wool has been prohibited. That of
beaver skins, of beaver wool, and of gum Senega has been subjected
to higher duties. Great Britain, by the conquest of Canada
and Senegal, having got almost the monopoly of those commodities.
That the mercantile system has not been very favourable to
the revenue of the great body of the people, to the annual
produce of the land and labour of the country, I have endeavoured
to show in the fourth book of this Inquiry. It seems not to
have been more favourable to the revenue of the sovereign,
so far at least as that revenue depends upon the duties of
customs.
In consequence of that system, the importation of several
sorts of goods has been prohibited altogether. This prohibition
has in some cases entirely prevented, and in others has very
much diminished the importation of those commodities by reducing
the importers to the necessity of smuggling. It has entirely
prevented the importation of foreign woollens, and it has very
much diminished that of foreign silks and velvets. In both
cases it has entirely annihilated the revenue of customs which
might have been levied upon such importation.
The high duties which have been imposed upon the importation
of many different sorts of foreign goods, in order to discourage
their consumption in Great Britain, have in many cases served
only to encourage smuggling, and in all cases have reduced
the revenue of the customs below what more moderate duties
would have afforded. The saying of Dr. Swift, that in the arithmetic
of the customs two and two, instead of making four, make sometimes
only one, holds perfectly true with regard to such heavy duties
which never could have been imposed had not the mercantile
system taught us, in many cases, to employ taxation as an instrument,
not of revenue, but of monopoly.
The bounties which are sometimes given upon the exportation
of home produce and manufactures, and the drawbacks which are
paid upon the re-exportation of the greater part of foreign
goods, have given occasion to many frauds, and to a species
of smuggling more destructive of the public revenue than any
other. In order to obtain the bounty or drawback, the goods,
it is well known, are sometimes shipped and sent to sea, but
soon afterwards clandestinely relanded in some other part of
the country. The defalcation of the revenue of customs occasioned
by the bounties and drawbacks, of which a great part are obtained
fraudulently, is very great. The gross produce of the customs
in the year which ended on the 5th of January 1755 amounted
to L5,068,000. The bounties which were paid out of this revenue,
though in that year there was no bounty upon corn, amounted
to L167,800. The drawbacks which were paid upon debentures
and certificates, to L2,156,800. Bounties and drawbacks together
amounted to L2,324,600. In consequence of these deductions
the revenue of the customs amounted only to L2,743,400: from
which, deducting L287,900 for the expense of management in
salaries and other incidents, the net revenue of the customs
for that year comes out to be L2,455,500. The expense of management
amounts in this manner to between five and six per cent upon
the gross revenue of the customs, and to something more than
ten per cent upon what remains of that revenue after deducting
what is paid away in bounties and drawbacks.
Heavy duties being imposed upon almost all goods imported,
our merchant importers smuggle as much and make entry of as
little as they can. Our merchant exporters, on the contrary,
make entry of more than they export; sometimes out of vanity,
and to pass for great dealers in goods which pay no duty, and
sometimes to gain a bounty or a drawback. Our exports, in consequence
of these different frauds, appear upon the customhouse books
greatly to overbalance our imports, to the unspeakable comfort
of those politicians who measure the national prosperity by
what they call the balance of trade.
All goods imported, unless particularly exempted, and such
exemptions are not very numerous, are liable to some duties
of customs. If any goods are imported not mentioned in the
book of rates, they are taxed at 4s. 9 9/20d. for every twenty
shillings value, according to the oath of the importer, that
is, nearly at five subsidies, or five poundage duties. The
book of rates is extremely comprehensive, and enumerates a
great variety of articles, many of them little used, and therefore
not well known. It is upon this account frequently uncertain
under what article a particular sort of goods ought to be classed,
and consequently what duty they ought to pay. Mistakes with
regard to this sometimes ruin the custom-house officer, and
frequently occasion much trouble, expense, and vexation to
the importer. In point of perspicuity, precision, and distinctness,
therefore, the duties of customs are much more inferior to
those of excise.
In order that the greater part of the members of any society
should contribute to the public revenue in proportion to their
respective expense, it does not seem necessary that every single
article of that expense should be taxed. The revenue which
is levied by the duties of excise is supposed to fall as equally
upon the contributors as that which is levied by the duties
of customs, and the duties of excise are imposed upon a few
articles only of the most general use and consumption. It has
been the opinion of many people that, by proper management,
the duties of customs might likewise, without any loss to the
public revenue, and with great advantage to foreign trade,
be confined to a few articles only.
The foreign articles of the most general use and consumption
in Great Britain seem at present to consist chiefly in foreign
wines and brandies; in some of the productions of America and
the West Indies- sugar, rum, tobacco, cocoanuts, etc.; and
in some of those of the East Indies- tea, coffee, china-ware,
spiceries of all kinds, several sorts of piece-goods, etc.
These different articles afford, perhaps, at present, the greater
part of the revenue which is drawn from the duties of customs.
The taxes which at present subsist upon foreign manufactures,
if you except those upon the few contained in the foregoing
enumeration, have the greater part of them been imposed for
the purpose, not of revenue, but of monopoly, or to give our
own merchants an advantage in the home market. By removing
all prohibitions, and by subjecting all foreign manufactures
to such moderate taxes as it was found from experience afforded
upon each article the greatest revenue to the public, our own
workmen might still have a considerable advantage in the home
market, and many articles, some of which at present afford
no revenue to government, and others a very inconsiderable
one, might afford a very great one.
High taxes, sometimes by diminishing the consumption of the
taxed commodities, and sometimes by encouraging smuggling,
frequently afford a smaller revenue to government than what
might be drawn from more moderate taxes.
When the diminution of revenue is the effect of the diminution
of consumption there can be but one remedy, and that is the
lowering of the tax.
When the diminution of the revenue is the diminution of the
revenue is the effect of the encouragement given to smuggling,
it may perhaps be remedied in two ways; either by diminishing
the temptation to smuggle, or by increasing the difficulty
of smuggling. The temptation to smuggle can be diminished only
by the lowering of the tax, and the difficulty of smuggling
can be increased only by establishing that system of administration
which is most proper for preventing it.
The excise laws, it appears, I believe, from experience, obstruct
and embarrass the operations of the smuggler much more effectually
than those of the customs. By introducing into the customs
a system of administration as similar to that of the excise
as the nature of the different duties will admit, the difficulty
of smuggling might be very much increased. This alteration,
it has been supposed by many people, might very easily be brought
about.
The importer of commodities liable to any duties of customs,
it has been said, might as his option be allowed either to
carry them to his own private warehouse, or to lodge them in
a warehouse provided either at his own expense or at that of
the public, but under the key of the custom-house officer,
and never to be opened but in his presence. If the merchant
carried them to his own private warehouse, the duties to be
immediately paid, and never afterwards to be drawn back, and
that warehouse to be at all times subject to the visit and
examination of the custom-house officer, in order to ascertain
how far the quantity contained in it corresponded with that
for which the duty had been paid. If he carried them to the
public warehouse, no duty to be paid till they were taken out
for home consumption. If taken out for exportation, to be duty
free, proper security being always given that they should be
so exported. The dealers in those particular commodities, either
by wholesale or retail, to be at all times subject to the visit
and examination of the custom-house officer, and to be obliged
to justify by proper certificates the payment of the duty upon
the whole quantity contained in their shops or warehouses.
What are called the excise-duties upon rum imported are at
present levied in this manner, and the same system of administration
might perhaps be extended to all duties upon goods imported,
provided always that those duties were, like the duties of
excise, confined to a few sorts of goods of the most general
use and consumption. If they were extended to almost all sorts
of goods, as at present, public warehouses of sufficient extent
could not easily be provided, and goods of a very delicate
nature, or of which the preservation required much care and
attention, could not safely be trusted by the merchant in any
warehouse but his own.
If by such a system of administration smuggling, to any considerable
extent, could be prevented even under pretty high duties, and
if every duty was occasionally either heightened or lowered
according as it was most likely, either the one way or the
other, to afford the greatest revenue to the state, taxation
being always employed as an instrument of revenue and never
of monopoly, it seems not improbable that a revenue at least
equal to the present net revenue of the customs might be drawn
from duties upon the importation of only a few sorts of goods
of the most general use and consumption, and that the duties
of customs might thus be brought to the same degree of simplicity,
certainty, and precision as those of excise. What the revenue
at present loses by drawbacks upon the re-exportation of foreign
goods which are afterwards relanded and consumed at home would
under this system be saved altogether. If to this saving, which
would alone be very considerable, were added the abolition
of all bounties upon the exportation of home produce in all
cases in which those bounties were not in reality drawbacks
of some duties of excise which had before been advanced, it
cannot well be doubted but that the net revenue of customs
might, after an alteration of this kind, be fully equal to
what it had ever been before.
If by such a change of system the public revenue suffered
no loss, the trade and manufactures of the country would certainly
gain a very considerable advantage. The trade in the commodities
not taxed, by far the greatest number, would be perfectly free,
and might be carried on to and from all parts of the world
with every possible advantage. Among those commodities would
be comprehended all the necessaries of life and all the materials
of manufacture. So far as the free importation of the necessaries
of life reduced their average money price in the home market
it would reduce the money price of labour, but without reducing
in any respect its real recompense. The value of money is in
proportion to the quantity of the necessaries of life which
it will purchase. That of the necessaries of life is altogether
independent of the quantity of money which can be had for them.
The reduction in the money price of labour would necessarily
be attended with a proportionable one in that of all home manufactures,
which would thereby gain some advantage in all foreign markets.
The price of some manufactures would be reduced in a still
greater proportion by the free importation of the raw materials.
If raw silk could be imported from China and Indostan duty
free, the silk manufacturers in England could greatly undersell
those of both France and Italy. There would be no occasion
to prohibit the importation of foreign silks and velvets. The
cheapness of their goods would secure to our own workmen not
only the possession of the home, but a very great command of
the foreign market. Even the trade in the commodities taxed
would be carried on with much more advantage than at present.
If those commodities were delivered out of the public warehouse
for foreign exportation, being in this case exempted from all
taxes, the trade in them would be perfectly free. The carrying
trade in all sorts of goods would under this system enjoy every
possible advantage. If those commodities were delivered out
for home consumption, the importer not being obliged to advance
the tax till he had an opportunity of selling his goods, either
to some dealer, or to some consumer, he could always afford
to sell them cheaper than if he had been obliged to advance
it at the moment of importation. Under the same taxes, the
foreign trade of consumption even in the taxed commodities
might in this manner be carried on with much more advantage
than it can be at present.
It was the object of the famous excise scheme of Sir Robert
Walpole to establish, with regard to wine and tobacco, a system
not very unlike that which is here proposed. But though the
bill which was then brought into Parliament comprehended those
two commodities, only it was generally supposed to be meant
as an introduction to a more extensive scheme of the same kind,
faction, combined with the interest of smuggling merchants,
raised so violent, though so unjust, a clamour against that
bill, that the minister thought proper to drop it, and from
a dread of exciting a clamour of the same kind, none of his
successors have dared to resume the project.
The duties upon foreign luxuries imported for home consumption,
though they sometimes fall upon the poor, fall principally
upon people of middling or more than middling fortune. Such
are, for example, the duties upon foreign wines, upon coffee,
chocolate, tea, sugar, etc.
The duties upon the cheaper luxuries of home produce destined
for home consumption fall pretty equally upon people of all
ranks in proportion to their respective expense. The poor pay
the duties upon malt, hops, beer, and ale, upon their own consumption:
the rich, upon both their own consumption and that of their
servants.
The whole consumption of the inferior ranks of people, or
of those below the middling rank, it must be observed, is in
every country much greater, not only in quantity, but in value,
than that of the middling and of those above the middling rank.
The whole expense of the inferior is much greater than that
of the superior ranks. In the first place, almost the whole
capital of every country is annually distributed among the
inferior ranks of people as the wages of productive labour.
Secondly, a great part of the revenue arising from both the
rent of land and the profits of stock is annually distributed
among the same rank in the wages and maintenance of menial
servants, and other unproductive labourers. Thirdly, some part
of the profits of stock belongs to the same rank as a revenue
arising from the employment of their small capitals. The amount
of the profits annually made by small shopkeepers, tradesmen,
and retailers of all kinds is everywhere very considerable,
and makes a very considerable portion of the annual produce.
Fourthly, and lastly, some part even of the rent of land belongs
to the same rank, a considerable part of those who are somewhat
below the middling rank, and a small part even to the lowest
rank, common labourers sometimes possessing in property an
acre or two of land. Though the expense of those inferior ranks
of people, therefore, taking them individually, is very small,
yet the whole mass of it, taking them collectively, amounts
always to by much the largest portion of the whole expense
of the society; what remains of the annual produce of the land
and labour of the country for the consumption of the superior
ranks being always much less, not only in quantity, but in
value. The taxes upon expense, therefore, which fall chiefly
upon that of the superior ranks of people, upon the smaller
portion of the annual produce, are likely to be much less productive
than either those which fall indifferently upon the expense
of all ranks, or even those which fall chiefly upon that of
the inferior ranks; than either those which fall indifferently
upon the whole annual produce, or those which fall chiefly
upon the larger portion of it. The excise upon the materials
and manufacture of home-made fermented and spirituous liquors
is accordingly, of all the different taxes upon expense, by
far the most productive; and this branch of the excise falls
very much, perhaps principally, upon the expense of the common
people. In the year which ended on the 5th of July 1775, the
gross produce of this branch of the excise amounted to L3,341,837
9s. 9d.
It must always be remembered, however, that it is the luxurious
and not the necessary expense of the inferior ranks of people
that ought ever to be taxed. The final payment of any tax upon
their necessary expense would fall altogether upon the superior
ranks of people; upon the smaller portion of the annual produce,
and not upon the greater. Such a tax must in all cases either
raise the wages of labour, or lessen the demand for it. It
could not raise the wages of labour without throwing the final
payment of the tax upon the superior ranks of people. It could
not lessen the demand for labour without lessening the annual
produce of the land and labour of the country, the fund from
which all taxes must be finally paid. Whatever might be the
state to which a tax of this kind reduced the demand for labour,
it must always raise wages higher than they otherwise would
be in that state, and the final payment of this enhancement
of wages must in all cases fall upon the superior ranks of
people.
Fermented liquors brewed, and spirituous liquors distilled,
not for sale, but for private use, are not in Great Britain
liable to any duties of excise. This exemption, of which the
object is to save private families from the odious visit and
examination of the tax-gatherer, occasions the burden of those
duties to fall frequently much lighter upon the rich than upon
the poor. It is not, indeed, very common to distil for private
use, though it is done sometimes. But in the country many middling
and almost all rich and great families brew their own beer.
Their strong beer, therefore, costs them eight shillings a
barrel less than it costs the common brewer, who must have
his profit upon the tax as well as upon all the other expense
which he advances. Such families, therefore, must drink their
beer at least nine or ten shillings a barrel cheaper than any
liquor of the same quality can be drunk by the common people,
to whom it is everywhere more convenient to buy their beer,
by little and little, from the brewery or the alehouse. Malt,
in the same manner, that is made for the use of a private family
is not liable to the visit or examination of the tax-gatherer;
but in this case the family must compound at seven shillings
and sixpence a head for the tax. Seven shillings and sixpence
are equal to the excise upon ten bushels of malt- a quantity
fully equal to what all the different members of any sober
family, men, women, and children, are at an average likely
to consume. But in rich and great families, where country hospitality
is much practised, the malt liquors consumed by the members
of the family make but a small part of the consumption of the
house. Either on account of this composition, however, or for
other reasons, it is not near so common to malt as to brew
for private use. It is difficult to imagine any equitable reason
why those who either brew or distil for private use should
not be subject to a composition of the same kind.
A greater revenue than what is at present drawn from all the
heavy taxes upon malt, beer, and ale might be raised, it has
frequently been said, by a much lighter tax upon malt, the
opportunities of defrauding the revenue being much greater
in a brewery than in a malt-house, and those who brew for private
use being exempted from all duties or composition for duties,
which is not the case with those who malt for private use.
In the porter brewery of London a quarter of malt is commonly
brewed into more than two barrels and a half, sometimes into
three barrels of porter. The different taxes upon malt amount
to six shillings a quarter, those upon strong beer and ale
to eight shillings a barrel. In the porter brewery, therefore,
the different taxes upon malt, beer, and ale amount to between
twenty-six and thirty shillings upon the produce of a quarter
of malt. In the country brewery for common country sale a quarter
of malt is seldom brewed into less than two barrels of strong
and one barrel of small beer, frequently into two barrels and
a half of strong beer. The different taxes upon small beer
amount to one shilling and fourpence a barrel. In the country
brewery, therefore, the different taxes upon malt, beer, and
ale seldom amount to less than twenty-three shillings and fourpence,
frequently to twenty-six shillings, upon the produce of a quarter
of malt. Taking the whole kingdom at an average, therefore,
the whole amount of the duties upon malt, beer, and ale cannot
be estimated at less than twenty-four or twenty-five shillings
upon the produce of a quarter of malt. But by taking off all
the different duties upon beer and ale, and by tripling the
malt-tax, or by raising it from six to eighteen shillings upon
the quarter of malt, a greater revenue, it is said, might be
raised by this single tax than what is at present drawn from
all those heavier taxes.
Under the old malt tax, indeed, is comprehended a tax of four
shillings upon the hogshead of cyder, and another of ten shillings
upon the barrel of mum. In 1774, the tax upon cyder produced
only L3083 6s. 8d. It probably fell somewhat short of its usual
amount, all the different taxes upon cyder having, that year,
produced less than ordinary. The tax upon mum, though much
heavier, is still less productive, on account of the smaller
consumption of that liquor. But to balance whatever may be
the ordinary amount of those two taxes, there is comprehended
under what is called the country excise, first, the old excise
of six shillings and eightpence upon the hogshead of cyder;
secondly, a like tax of six shillings and eightpence upon the
hogshead of verjuice; thirdly, another of eight shillings and
ninepence upon the hogshead of vinegar; and, lastly, a fourth
tax of elevenpence upon the gallon of mead or metheglin: the
produce of those different taxes will probably much more than
counterbalance that of the duties imposed by what is called
the annual malt tax upon cyder and mum.
L s. d.
In 1772, the old malt-tax produced 722,023 11 11
The additional 356,776 7 9 3/4
In 1773, the old tax produced 561,627 3 7 1/2
The additional 278,650 15 3 3/4
In 1774, the old tax produced 624,614 17 5 3/4
The additional 310,745 2 8 1/2
In 1775, the old tax produced 657,357 0 8 1/4
The additional 323,785 12 6 1/4
---------------------------
4)3,835,580 12 0 3/4
---------------------------
Average of these four years 958,895 3 0 3/16
---------------------------
In 1772, the country excise produced 1,243,128 5 3
The London brewery 408,260 7 2 3/4
In 1773, the country excise 1,245,808 3 3
The London brewery 405,406 17 10 1/2
In 1774, the country excise 1,246,373 14 5 1/2
The London brewery 320,601 18 0 1/4
In 1775, the country excise 1,214,583 6 1
The London brewery 463,670 7 0 1/4
---------------------------
4)6,547,832 19 2 1/4
---------------------------
Average of these four years 1,636,958 4 9 1/2
To which adding the average malt-tax, or 958,895 3 0 3/16
The whole amount of those different
taxes comes out to be 2,595,853 7 9 11/19
---------------------------
But by tripling the malt-tax, or by
raising it from six to eighteen
shillings upon the quarter of malt,
that single tax would produce 2,876,685 9 0 9/16
A sum which exceeds the foregoing by 280,832 1 2 14/16
Malt is consumed not only in the brewery of beer and ale,
but in the manufacture of wines and spirits. If the malt tax
were to be raised to eighteen shillings upon the quarter, it
might be necessary to make some abatement in the different
excises which are imposed upon those particular sorts of low
wines and spirits of which malt makes any part of the materials.
In what are called malt spirits it makes commonly but a third
part of the materials, the other two-thirds being either raw
barley, or one-third barley and one-third wheat. In the distillery
of malt spirits, both the opportunity and the temptation to
smuggle are much greater than either in a brewery or in a malt-house;
the opportunity on account of the smaller bulk and greater
value of the commodity, and the temptation on account of the
superior height of the duties, which amount to 3s. 10 2/3d.*
upon the gallon of spirits. By increasing the duties upon malt,
and reducing those upon the distillery, both the opportunities
and the temptation to smuggle would be diminished, which might
occasion a still further augmentation of revenue.
* Though the duties directly imposed upon proof spirits amount
only to 2s. 6d. per gallon, these added to the duties upon
the low wines, from which they are distilled, amount to 3s.
10 2/3d. Both low wines and proof spirits are, to prevent frauds,
now rated according to what they gauge in the wash.
It has for some time past been the policy of Great Britain
to discourage the consumption of spirituous liquors, on account
of their supposed tendency to ruin the health and to corrupt
the morals of the common people. According to this policy,
the abatement of the taxes upon the distillery ought not to
be so great as to reduce, in any respect, the price of those
liquors. Spirituous liquors might remain as dear as ever, while
at the same time the wholesome and invigorating liquors of
beer and ale might be considerably reduced in their price.
The people might thus be in part relieved from one of the burdens
of which they at present complain the most, while at the same
time the revenue might be considerably augmented.
The objections of Dr. Davenant to this alteration in the present
system of excise duties seem to be without foundation. Those
objections are, that the tax, instead of dividing itself as
at present pretty equally upon the profit of the maltster,
upon that of the brewer, and upon that of the retailer, would,
so far as it affected profit, fall altogether upon that of
the maltster; that the maltster could not so easily get back
the amount of the tax in the advanced price of his malt as
the brewer and retailer in the advanced price of their liquor;
and that so heavy a tax upon malt might reduce the rent and
profit of barley land.
No tax can ever reduce, for any considerable time, the rate
of profit in any particular trade which must always keep its
level with other trades in the neighbourhood. The present duties
upon malt, beer, and ale do not affect the profits of the dealers
in those commodities, who all get back the tax with an additional
profit in the enhanced price of their goods. A tax, indeed,
may render the goods upon which it is imposed so dear as to
diminish the consumption of them. But the consumption of malt
is in malt liquors, and a tax of eighteen shillings upon the
quarter of malt could not well render those liquors dearer
than the different taxes, amounting to twenty-four or twenty-five
shillings, do at present. Those liquors, on the contrary, would
probably become cheaper, and the consumption of them would
be more likely to increase than to diminish.
It is not very easy to understand why it should be more difficult
for the maltster to get back eighteen shillings in the advanced
price of his malt than it is at present for the brewer to get
back twenty-four or twenty-five, sometimes thirty, shillings
in that of his liquor. The maltster, indeed, instead of a tax
of six shillings, would be obliged to advance one of eighteen
shillings upon every quarter of malt. But the brewer is at
present obliged to advance a tax of twenty-four or twenty-five,
sometimes thirty, shillings upon every quarter of malt which
he brews. It could not be more inconvenient for the maltster
to advance a lighter tax than it is at present for the brewer
to advance a heavier one. The maltster doth not always keep
in his granaries a stock of malt which it will require a longer
time to dispose of than the stock of beer and ale which the
brewer frequently keeps in his cellars. The former, therefore,
may frequently get the returns of his money as soon as the
latter. But whatever inconveniency might arise to the maltster
from being obliged to advance a heavier tax, it could easily
be remedied by granting him a few months' longer credit than
is at present commonly given to the brewer.
Nothing could reduce the rent and profit of barley land which
did not reduce the demand for barley. But a change of system
which reduced the duties upon a quarter of malt brewed into
beer and ale from twenty-four and twenty-five shillings to
eighteen shillings would be more likely to increase than diminish
that demand. The rent and profit of barley land, besides, must
always be nearly equal to those of other equally fertile and
equally well-cultivated land. If they were less, some part
of the barley land would soon be turned to some other purpose;
and if they were greater, more land would soon be turned to
the raising of barley. When the ordinary price of any particular
produce of land is at what may be called a monopoly price,
a tax upon it necessarily reduces the rent and profit of the
land which grows it. A tax upon the produce of those precious
vineyards of which the wine falls so much short of the effectual
demand that its price is always above the natural proportion
to that of the produce of other equally fertile and equally
well cultivated land would necessarily reduce the rent and
profit of those vineyards. The price of the wines being already
the highest that could be got for the quantity commonly sent
to market, it could not be raised higher without diminishing
that quantity, and the quantity could not be diminished without
still greater loss, because the lands could not be turned to
any other equally valuable produce. The whole weight of the
tax, therefore, would fall upon the rent and profit- properly
upon the rent of the vineyard. When it has been proposed to
lay any new tax upon sugar, our sugar planters have frequently
complained that the whole weight of such taxes fell, not upon
the consumer, but upon the producer, they never having been
able to raise the price of their sugar after the tax higher
than it was before. The price had, it seems, before the tax
been a monopoly price, and the argument adduced to show that
sugar was an improper subject of taxation demonstrated, perhaps,
that it was a proper one, the gains of monopolists, whenever
they can be come at, being certainly of all subjects the most
proper. But the ordinary price of barley has never been a monopoly
price, and the rent and profit of barley land have never been
above their natural proportion to those of other equally fertile
and equally well-cultivated land. The different taxes which
have been imposed upon malt, beer, and ale have never lowered
the price of barley, have never reduced the rent and profit
of barley land. The price of malt to the brewer has constantly
risen in proportion to the taxes imposed upon it, and those
taxes, together with the different duties upon beer and ale,
have constantly either raised the price, or what comes to the
same thing, reduced the quality of those commodities to the
consumer. The final payment of those taxes has fallen constantly
upon the consumer, and not upon the producer.
The only people likely to suffer by the change of system here
proposed are those who brew for their own private use. But
the exemption which this superior rank of people at present
enjoy from very heavy taxes which are paid by the poor labourer
and artificer is surely most unjust and unequal, and ought
to be taken away, even though this change was never to take
place. It has probably been the interest of this superior order
of people, however, which has hitherto prevented a change of
system that could not well fail both to increase the revenue
and to relieve the people.
Besides such duties as those of customs and excise above mentioned,
there are several others which affect the price of goods more
unequally and more indirectly. Of this kind are the duties
which in French are called Peages, which in old Saxon times
were called Duties of Passage, and which seem to have been
originally established for the same purpose as our turnpike
tolls, or the tolls upon our canals and navigable rivers, for
the maintenance of the road or of the navigation. Those duties,
when applied to such purposes, are most properly imposed according
to the bulk or weight of the goods. As they were originally
local and provincial duties, applicable to local and provincial
purposes, the administration of them was in most cases entrusted
to the particular town, parish, or lordship in which they were
levied, such communities being in some way or other supposed
to be accountable for the application. The sovereign, who is
altogether unaccountable, has in many countries assumed to
himself the administration of those duties, and though he has
in most cases enhanced very much the duty, he has in many entirely
neglected the application. If the turnpike tolls of Great Britain
should ever become one of the resources of government, we may
learn, by the example of many other nations, what would probably
be the consequence. Such tolls are no doubt finally paid by
the consumer; but the consumer is not taxed in proportion to
his expense when he pays, not according to the value, but according
to the bulk or weight of what he consumes. When such duties
are imposed, not according to the bulk or weight, but according
to the supposed value of the goods, they become properly a
sort of inland customs or excises which obstruct very much
the most important of all branches of commerce, the interior
commerce of the country.
In some small states duties similar to those passage duties
are imposed upon goods carried across the territory, either
by land or by water, from one foreign country to another. These
are in some countries called transit-duties. Some of the little
Italian states which are situated upon the Po and the rivers
which run into it derive some revenue from duties of this kind
which are paid altogether by foreigners, and which, perhaps,
are the only duties that one state can impose upon the subjects
of another without obstructing in any respect the industry
or commerce of its own. The most important transit-duty in
the world is that levied by the King of Denmark upon all merchant
ships which pass through the Sound.
Such taxes upon luxuries as the greater part of the duties
of customs and excise, though they all fall indifferently upon
every different species of revenue, and are paid finally, or
without any retribution, by whoever consumes the commodities
upon which they are imposed, yet they do not always fall equally
or proportionably upon the revenue of every individual. As
every man's humour regulates the degree of his consumption,
every man contributes rather according to his humour than in
proportion to his revenue; the profuse contribute more, the
parsimonious less, than their proper proportion. During the
minority of a man of great fortune he contributes commonly
very little, by his consumption, towards the support of that
state from whose protection he derives a great revenue. Those
who live in another country contribute nothing, by their consumption,
towards the support of the government of that country in which
is situated the source of their revenue. If in this latter
country there should be no land-tax, nor any considerable duty
upon the transference either of movable or of immovable property,
as is the case in Ireland, such absentees may derive a great
revenue from the protection of a government to the support
of which they do not contribute a single shilling. This inequality
is likely to be greatest in a country of which the government
is in some respects subordinate and dependent upon that of
some other. The people who possess the most extensive property
in the dependent will in this case generally choose to live
in the governing country. Ireland is precisely in this situation,
and we cannot, therefore, wonder that the proposal of a tax
upon absentees should be so very popular in that country. It
might, perhaps, be a little difficult to ascertain either what
sort or what degree of absence would subject a man to be taxed
as an absentee, or at what precise time the tax should either
begin or end. If you except, however, this very peculiar situation,
any inequality in the contribution of individuals which can
arise from such taxes is much more than compensated by the
very circumstance which occasions that inequality- the circumstance
that every man's contribution is altogether voluntary, it being
altogether in his power either to consume or not to consume
the commodity taxed. Where such taxes, therefore, are properly
assessed, and upon proper commodities, they are paid with less
grumbling than any other. When they are advanced by the merchant
or manufacturer, the consumer, who finally pays them, soon
comes to confound them with the price of the commodities, and
almost forgets that he pays any tax.
Such taxes are or may be perfectly certain, or may be assessed
so as to leave no doubt concerning either what ought to be
paid, or when it ought to be paid; concerning either the quantity
or the time of payment. Whatever uncertainty there may sometimes
be, either in the duties of customs in Great Britain, or in
other duties of the same kind in other countries, it cannot
arise from the nature of those duties, but from the inaccurate
or unskilful manner in which the law that imposes them is expressed.
Taxes upon luxuries generally are, and always may be, paid
piecemeal, or in proportion as the contributors have occasion
to purchase the goods upon which they are imposed. In the time
and mode of payment they are, or may be, of all taxes the most
convenient. Upon the whole, such taxes, are, perhaps, as agreeable
to the three first of the four general maxims concerning taxation
as any other. They offend in every respect against the fourth.
Such taxes, in proportion to what they bring into the public
treasury of the state, always take out or keep out of the pockets
of the people more than almost any other taxes. They seem to
do this in all the four different ways in which it is possible
to do it.
First, the levying of such taxes, even when imposed in the
most judicious manner, requires a great number of custom-house
and excise officers, whose salaries and perquisites are a real
tax upon the people, which brings nothing into the treasury
of the state. This expense, however, it must be acknowledged,
is more moderate in Great Britain than in most other countries.
In the year which ended on the 5th of July 1775, the gross
produce of the different duties, under the management of the
commissioners of excise in England, amounted to L5,507,308
18s. 8 1/4d., which was levied at an expense of little more
than five and a half per cent. From this gross produce, however,
there must be deducted what was paid away in bounties and drawbacks
upon the exportation of excisable goods, which will reduce
the net produce below five millions.* The levying of the salt
duty, an excise duty, but under a different management, is
much more expensive. The net revenue of the customs does not
amount to two millions and a half, which is levied at an expense
of more than ten per cent in the salaries of officers, and
other incidents. But the perquisites of custom-house officers
are everywhere much greater than their salaries; at some ports
more than double or triple those salaries. If the salaries
of officers, and other incidents, therefore, amount to more
than ten per cent upon the net revenue of the customs, the
whole expense of levying that revenue may amount, in salaries
and perquisites together, to more than twenty or thirty per
cent. The officers of excise receive few or no perquisites,
and the administration of that branch of the revenue, being
of more recent establishment, is in general less corrupted
than that of the customs, into which length of time has introduced
and authorized many abuses. By charging upon malt the whole
revenue which is at present levied by the different duties
upon malt and malt liquors, a saving, it is supposed, of more
than fifty thousand pounds might be made in the annual expense
of the excise. By confining the duties of customs to a few
sorts of goods, and by levying those duties according to the
excise laws, a much greater saving might probably be made in
the annual expense of the customs.
* The net produce of that year, after deducting all expenses
and allowances, amounted to L4,975,652 19s. 6d.
Secondly, such taxes necessarily occasion some obstruction
or discouragement to certain branches of industry. As they
always raise the price of the commodity taxed, they so far
discourage its consumption, and consequently its production.
If it is a commodity of home growth or manufacture, less labour
comes to be employed in raising and producing it. If it is
a foreign commodity of which the tax increases in this manner
the price, the commodities of the same kind which are made
at home may thereby, indeed, gain some advantage in the home
market, and a greater quantity of domestic industry may thereby
be turned toward preparing them. But though this rise of price
in a foreign commodity may encourage domestic industry in one
particular branch, it necessarily discourages that industry
in almost every other. The dearer the Birmingham manufacturer
buys his foreign wine, the cheaper he necessarily sells that
part of his hardware with which, or, what comes to the same
thing, with the price of which he buys it. That part of his
hardware, therefore, becomes of less value to him, and he has
less encouragement to work at it. The dearer the consumers
in one country pay for the surplus produce of another, the
cheaper they necessarily sell that part of their own surplus
produce with which, or, what comes to the same thing, with
the price of which they buy it. That part of their own surplus
produce becomes of less value to them, and they have less encouragement
to increase its quantity. All taxes upon consumable commodities,
therefore, tend to reduce the quantity of productive labour
below what it otherwise would be, either in preparing the commodities
taxed, if they are home commodities, or in preparing those
with which they are purchased, if they are foreign commodities.
Such taxes, too, always alter, more or less, the natural direction
of national industry, and turn it into a channel always different
from, and generally less advantageous than that in which it
would have run of its own accord.
Thirdly, the hope of evading such taxes by smuggling gives
frequent occasion to forfeitures and other penalties which
entirely ruin the smuggler; a person who, though no doubt highly
blamable for violating the laws of his country, is frequently
incapable of violating those of natural justice, and would
have been, in every respect, an excellent citizen had not the
laws of his country made that a crime which nature never meant
to be so. In those corrupted governments where there is at
least a general suspicion of much unnecessary expense, and
great misapplication of the public revenue, the laws which
guard it are little respected. Not many people are scrupulous
about smuggling when, without perjury, they can find any easy
and safe opportunity of doing so. To pretend to have any scruple
about buying smuggled goods, though a manifest encouragement
to the violation of the revenue laws, and to the perjury which
almost always attends it, would in most countries be regarded
as one of those pedantic pieces of hypocrisy which, instead
of gaining credit with anybody, serve only to expose the person
who affects to practise them to the suspicion of being a greater
knave than most of his neighbours. By this indulgence of the
public, the smuggler is often encouraged to continue a trade
which he is thus taught to consider as in some measure innocent,
and when the severity of the revenue laws is ready to fall
upon him, he is frequently disposed to defend with violence
what he has been accustomed to regard as his just property.
From being at first, perhaps, rather imprudent than criminal,
he at last too often becomes one of the hardiest and most determined
violators of the laws of society. By the ruin of the smuggler,
his capital, which had before been employed in maintaining
productive labour, is absorbed either in the revenue of the
state or in that of the revenue officer, and is employed in
maintaining unproductive, to the diminution of the general
capital of the society and of the useful industry which it
might otherwise have maintained.
Fourthly, such taxes, by subjecting at least the dealers in
the taxed commodities to the frequent visits and odious examination
of the tax-gatherers, expose them sometimes, no doubt, to some
degree of oppression, and always to much trouble and vexation;
and though vexation, as has already been said, is not, strictly
speaking, expense, it is certainly equivalent to the expense
at which every man would be willing to redeem himself from
it. The laws of excise, though more effectual for the purpose
for which they were instituted, are, in this respect, more
vexatious than those of the customs. When a merchant has imported
goods subject to certain duties of customs, when he has paid
those duties, and lodged the goods in his warehouse, he is
not in most cases liable to any further trouble or vexation
from the custom-house officer. It is otherwise with goods subject
to duties of excise. The dealers have no respite from the continual
visits and examination of the excise officers. The duties of
excise are, upon this account, more unpopular than those of
the customs; and so are the officers who levy them. Those officers,
it is pretended, though in general, perhaps, they do their
duty fully as well as those of the customs, yet as that duty
obliges them to be frequently very troublesome to some of their
neighbours, commonly contract a certain hardness of character
which the others frequently have not. This observation, however,
may very probably be the mere suggestion of fraudulent dealers
whose smuggling is either prevented or detected by their diligence.
The inconveniencies, however, which are, perhaps, in some
degree inseparable from taxes upon consumable commodities,
fall as light upon the people of Great Britain as upon those
of any other country of which the government is nearly as expensive.
Our state is not perfect, and might be mended, but it is as
good or better than that of most of our neighbours.
In consequence of the notion that duties upon consumable goods
were taxes upon the profits of merchants, those duties have,
in some countries, been repeated upon every successive sale
of the goods. If the profits of the merchant importer or merchant
manufacturer were taxed, equality seemed to require that those
of all the middle buyers who intervened between either of them
and the consumer should likewise be taxed. The famous alcavala
of Spain seems to have been established upon this principle.
It was at first a tax of ten per cent, afterwards of fourteen
per cent, and is at present of only six per cent upon the sale
of every sort of property whether movable or immovable, and
it is repeated every time the property is sold. The levying
of this tax requires a multitude of revenue officers sufficient
to guard the transportation of goods, not only from one province
to another, but from one shop to another. It subjects not only
the dealers in some sorts of goods, but those in all sorts,
every farmer, every manufacturer, every merchant and shopkeeper,
to the continual visits and examination of the tax-gatherers.
Through the greater part of a country in which a tax of this
kind is established nothing can be produced for distant sale.
The produce of every part of the country must be proportioned
to the consumption of the neighborhood. It is to the alcavala,
accordingly, that Ustaritz imputes the ruin of the manufactures
of Spain. He might have imputed to it likewise the declension
of agriculture, it being imposed not only upon manufactures,
but upon the rude produce of the land.
In the kingdom of Naples there is a similar tax of three per
cent upon the value of all contracts, and consequently upon
that of all contracts of sale. It is both lighter than the
Spanish tax, and the greater part of towns and parishes are
allowed to pay a composition in lieu of it. They levy this
composition in what manner they please, generally in a way
that gives no interruption to the interior commerce of the
place. The Neapolitan tax, therefore, is not near so ruinous
as the Spanish one.
The uniform system of taxation which, with a few exceptions
of no great consequence, takes place in all the different parts
of the United Kingdom of Great Britain, leaves the interior
commerce of the country, the inland and coasting trade, almost
entirely free. The inland trade is almost perfectly free, and
the greater part of goods may be carried from one end of the
kingdom to the other without requiring any permit or let-pass,
without being subject to question, visit, or examination from
the revenue officers. There are a few exceptions, but they
are such as can give no interruption to any important branch
of the inland commerce of the country. Goods carried coastwise,
indeed, require certificates or coast-cockets. If you except
coals, however, the rest are almost all duty-free. This freedom
of interior commerce, the effect of the uniformity of the system
of taxation, is perhaps one of the principal causes of the
prosperity of Great Britain, every great country being necessarily
the best and most extensive market for the greater part of
the productions of its own industry. If the same freedom, in
consequence of the same uniformity, could be extended to Ireland
and the plantations, both the grandeur of the state and the
prosperity of every part of the empire would probably be still
greater than at present.
In France, the different revenue laws which take place in
the different provinces require a multitude of revenue officers
to surround not only the frontiers of the kingdom, but those
of almost each particular province, in order either to prevent
the importation of certain goods, or to subject it to the payment
of certain duties, to the no small interruption of the interior
commerce of the country. Some provinces are allowed to compound
for the gabelle or salt-tax. Others are exempted from it altogether.
Some provinces are exempted from the exclusive sale of tobacco,
which the farmers-general enjoy through the greater part of
the kingdom. The aides, which correspond to the excise in England,
are very different in different provinces. Some provinces are
exempted from them, and pay a composition or equivalent. In
those in which they take place and are in farm there are many
local duties which do not extend beyond a particular town or
district. The traites, which correspond to our customs, divide
the kingdom into three great parts; first, the provinces subject
to the tariff of 1664, which are called the provinces of the
five great farms, and under which are comprehended Picardy,
Normandy, and the greater part of the interior provinces of
the kingdom; secondly, the provinces subject to the tariff
of 1667, which are called the provinces reckoned foreign, and
under which are comprehended the greater part of the frontier
provinces; and, thirdly, those provinces which are said to
be treated as foreign, or which, because they are allowed a
free commerce with foreign countries, are in their commerce
with other provinces of France subjected to the same duties
as other foreign countries. These are Alsace, the three bishoprics
of Metz, Toul, and Verdun, and the three cities of Dunkirk,
Bayonne, and Marseilles. Both in the provinces of the five
great farms (called so on account of an ancient division of
the duties of customs into five great branches, each of which
was originally the subject of a particular farm, though they
are now all united into one), and in those which are said to
be reckoned foreign, there are many local duties which do not
extend beyond a particular town or district. There are some
such even in the provinces which are said to be treated as
foreign, particularly in the city of Marseilles. It is unnecessary
to observe how much both the restraints upon the interior commerce
of the country and the number of the revenue officers must
be multiplied in order to guard the frontiers of those different
provinces and districts which are subject to such different
systems of taxation.
Over and above the general restraints arising from this complicated
system of revenue laws, the commerce of wine, after corn perhaps
the most important production of France, is in the greater
part of the provinces subject to particular restraints, arising
from the favour which has been shown to the vineyards of particular
provinces and districts, above those of others. The provinces
most famous for their wines, it will be found, I believe, are
those in which the trade in that article is subject to the
fewest restraints of this kind. The extensive market which
such provinces enjoy, encourages good management both in the
cultivation of their vineyards, and in the subsequent preparation
of their wines.
Such various and complicated revenue laws are not peculiar
to France. The little duchy of Milan is divided into six provinces,
in each of which there is a different system of taxation with
regard to several different sorts of consumable goods. The
still smaller territories of the Duke of Parma are divided
into three or four, each of which has, in the same manner,
a system of its own. Under such absurd management, nothing
but the great fertility of the soil and happiness of the climate
could preserve such countries from soon relapsing into the
lowest state of poverty and barbarism.
Taxes upon consumable commodities may either be levied by
an administration of which the officers are appointed by government
and are immediately accountable to government, of which the
revenue must in this case vary from year to year according
to the occasional variations in the produce of the tax, or
they may be let in farm for a rent certain, the farmer being
allowed to appoint his own officers, who, though obliged to
levy the tax in the manner directed by the law, are under his
immediate inspection, and are immediately accountable to him.
The best and most frugal way of levying a tax can never be
by farm. Over and above what is necessary for paying the stipulated
rent, the salaries of the officers, and the whole expense of
administration, the farmer must always draw from the produce
of the tax a certain profit proportioned at least to the advance
which he makes, to the risk which he runs, to the trouble which
he is at, and to the knowledge and skill which it requires
to manage so very complicated a concern. Government, by establishing
an administration under their own immediate inspection of the
same kind with that which the farmer establishes, might at
least save this profit, which is almost always exorbitant.
To farm any considerable branch of the public revenue requires
either a great capital or a great credit; circumstances which
would alone restrain the competition for such an undertaking
to a very small number of people. Of the few who have this
capital or credit, a still smaller number have the necessary
knowledge or experience; another circumstance which restrains
the competition still further. The very few, who are in condition
to become competitors, find it more for their interest to combine
together; to become co-partners instead of competitors, and
when the farm is set up to auction, to offer no rent but what
is much below the real value. In countries where the public
revenues are in farm, the farmers are generally the most opulent
people. Their wealth would alone excite the public indignation,
and the vanity which almost always accompanies such upstart
fortunes, the foolish ostentation with which they commonly
display that wealth, excites that indignation still more.
The farmers of the public revenue never find the laws too
severe which punish any attempt to evade the payment of a tax.
They have no bowels for the contributors, who are not their
subjects, and whose universal bankruptcy, if it should happen
the day after their farm is expired, would not much affect
their interest. In the greatest exigencies of the state, when
the anxiety of the sovereign for the exact payment of his revenue
is necessarily the greatest, they seldom fail to complain that
without laws more rigorous than those which actually take place,
it will be impossible for them to pay even the usual rent.
In those moments of public distress their demands cannot be
disputed. The revenue laws, therefore, become gradually more
and more severe. The most sanguinary are always to be found
in countries where the greater part of the public revenue is
in farm; the mildest, in countries where it is levied under
the immediate inspection of the sovereign. Even a bad sovereign
feels more compassion for his people than can ever be expected
from the farmers of his revenue. He knows that the permanent
grandeur of his family depends upon the prosperity of his people,
and he will never knowingly ruin that prosperity for the sake
of any momentary interest of his own. It is otherwise with
the farmers of his revenue, whose grandeur may frequently be
the effect of the ruin, and not of the prosperity of his people.
A tax is sometimes not only farmed for a certain rent, but
the farmer has, besides, the monopoly of the commodity taxed.
In France, the duties upon tobacco and salt are levied in this
manner. In such cases the farmer, instead of one, levies two
exorbitant profits upon the people; the profit of the farmer,
and the still more exorbitant one of the monopolist. Tobacco
being a luxury, every man is allowed to buy or not to buy as
he chooses. But salt being a necessary, every man is obliged
to buy of the farmer a certain quantity of it; because, if
he did not buy this quantity of the farmer, he would, it is
presumed, buy it of some smuggler. The taxes upon both commodities
are exorbitant. The temptation to smuggle consequently is to
many people irresistible, while at the same time the rigour
of the law, and the vigilance of the farmer's officers, render
the yielding to that temptation almost certainly ruinous. The
smuggling of salt and tobacco sends every year several hundred
people to the galleys, besides a very considerable number whom
it sends to the gibbet. Those taxes levied in this manner yield
a very considerable revenue to government. In 1767, the farm
of tobacco was let for twenty-two millions five hundred and
forty-one thousand two hundred and seventy-eight livres a year.
That of salt, for thirty-six millions four hundred and ninety-four
thousand four hundred and four livres. The farm in both cases
was to commence in 1768, and to last for six years. Those who
consider the blood of the people as nothing in comparison with
the revenue of the prince, may perhaps approve of this method
of levying taxes. Similar taxes and monopolies of salt and
tobacco have been established in many other countries; particularly
in the Austrian and Prussian dominions, and in the greater
part of the states of Italy.
In France, the greater part of the actual revenue of the crown
is derived from eight different sources; the taille, the capitation,
the two vingtiemes, the gabelles, the aides, the traites, the
domaine, and the farm of tobacco. The five last are, in the
greater part of the provinces, under farm. The three first
are everywhere levied by an administration under the immediate
inspection and direction of government, and it is universally
acknowledged that, in proportion to what they take out of the
pockets of the people, they bring more into the treasury of
the prince than the other five, of which the administration
is much more wasteful and expensive.
The finances of France seem, in their present state, to admit
of three very obvious reformations. First, by abolishing the
taille and the capitation, and by increasing the number of
vingtiemes, so as to produce an additional revenue equal to
the amount of those other taxes, the revenue of the crown might
be preserved; the expense of collection might be much diminished;
the vexation of the inferior ranks of people, which the taille
and capitation occasion, might be entirely prevented; and the
superior ranks might not be more burdened than the greater
part of them are at present. The vingtieme, I have already
observed, is a tax very nearly of the same kind with what is
called the land-tax of England. The burden of the taille, it
is acknowledged, falls finally upon the proprietors of land;
and as the greater part of the capitation is assessed upon
those who are subject to the taille at so much a pound of that
other tax, the final payment of the greater part of it must
likewise fall upon the same order of people. Though the number
of the vingtiemes, therefore, was increased so as to produce
an additional revenue equal to the amount of both those taxes,
the superior ranks of people might not be more burdened than
they are at present. Many individuals no doubt would, on account
of the great inequalities with which the taille is commonly
assessed upon the estates and tenants of different individuals.
The interest and opposition of such favoured subjects are the
obstacles most likely to prevent this or any other reformation
of the same kind. Secondly, by rendering the gabelle, the aides,
the traites, the taxes upon tobacco, all the different customs
and excises, uniform in all the different parts of the kingdom,
those taxes might be levied at much less expense, and the interior
commerce of the kingdom might be rendered as free as that of
England. Thirdly, and lastly, by subjecting all those taxes
to an administration under the immediate inspection and direction
of government, the exorbitant profits of the farmers-general
might be added to the revenue of the state. The opposition
arising from the private interest of individuals is likely
to be as effectual for preventing the two last as the first-mentioned
scheme of reformation.
The French system of taxation seems, in every respect, inferior
to the British. In Great Britain ten millions sterling are
annually levied upon less than eight millions of people without
its being possible to say that any particular order is oppressed.
From the collections of the Abbe Expilly, and the observations
of the author of the Essay upon legislation and commerce of
corn, it appears probable that France, including the provinces
of Lorraine and Bar, contains about twenty-three or twenty-four
millions of people three times the number perhaps contained
in Great Britain. The soil and climate of France are better
than those of Great Britain. The country has been much longer
in a state of improvement and cultivation, and is, upon that
account, better stocked with all those things which it requires
a long time to raise up and accumulate, such as great towns,
and convenient and well-built houses, both in town and country.
With these advantages it might be expected that in France a
revenue of thirty millions might be levied for the support
of the state with as little inconveniency as a revenue of ten
millions is in Great Britain. In 1765 and 1766, the whole revenue
paid into the treasury of France, according to the best, though,
I acknowledge, very imperfect, accounts which I could get of
it, usually run between 308 and 325 millions of livres; that
is, it did not amount to fifteen millions sterling; not the
half of what might have been expected had the people contributed
in the same proportion to their numbers as the people of Great
Britain. The people of France, however, it is generally acknowledged,
are much more oppressed by taxes than the people of Great Britain.
France, however, is certainly the great empire in Europe which,
after that of Great Britain, enjoys the mildest and most indulgent
government.
In Holland the heavy taxes upon the necessaries of life have
ruined, it is said, their principal manufactures, and are likely
to discourage gradually even their fisheries and their trade
in shipbuilding. The taxes upon the necessaries of life are
inconsiderable in Great Britain, and no manufacture has hitherto
been ruined by them. The British taxes which bear hardest on
manufactures are some duties upon the importation of raw materials,
particularly upon that of raw silk. The revenue of the states-general
and of the different cities, however, is said to amount to
more than five millions two hundred and fifty thousand pounds
sterling; and as the inhabitants of the United Provinces cannot
well be supposed to amount to more than a third part of those
of Great Britain, they must, in proportion to their number,
be much more heavily taxed.
After all the proper subjects of taxation have been exhausted,
if the exigencies of the state still continue to require new
taxes, they must be imposed upon improper ones. The taxes upon
the necessaries of life, therefore, the wisdom of that republic
which, in order to acquire and to maintain its independency,
has, in spite of its great frugality, been involved in such
expensive wars as have obliged it to contract great debts.
The singular countries of Holland and Zeeland, besides, require
a considerable expense even to preserve their existence, or
to prevent their being swallowed up by the sea, which must
have contributed to increase considerably the load of taxes
in those two provinces. The republican form of government seems
to be the principal support of the present grandeur of Holland.
The owners of great capitals, the great mercantile families,
have generally either some direct share or some indirect influence
in the administration of that government. For the sake of the
respect and authority which they derive from this situation,
they are willing to live in a country where their capital,
if they employ it themselves, will bring them less profit,
and if they lend it to another, less interest; and where the
very moderate revenue which they can draw from it will purchase
less of the necessaries and conveniences of life than in any
other part of Europe. The residence of such wealthy people
necessarily keeps alive, in spite of all disadvantages, a certain
degree of industry in the country. Any public calamity which
should destroy the republican form of government, which should
throw the whole administration into the hands of nobles and
of soldiers, which should annihilate altogether the importance
of those wealthy merchants, would soon render it disagreeable
to them to live in a country where they were no longer likely
to be much respected. They would remove both their residences
and their capitals to some other country, and the industry
and commerce of Holland would soon follow the capitals which
supported them.
..
..
..
CLICK
HERE TO DISCUSS THIS BOOK
|
|